Financial and Monetary Systems

Why doesn’t the US redistribute more?

Nick Bunker
Policy Analyst, Washington Center for Equitable Growth
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Financial and Monetary Systems?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Financial and Monetary Systems is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Financial and Monetary Systems

Economists, policymakers, and the general public are all well aware that the United States has a much higher level of income inequality than other developed countries. But what sets it apart from other nations isn’t the distribution of income but rather the level of redistribution. With high levels of inequality, economists would expect the median U.S. voter to push for more redistribution as the top earners pull further away from those on the middle and bottom of the income ladder.

So why doesn’t the U.S. government redistribute more?

A paper presented at the just-concluded annual Allied Social Sciences Associations meeting in Boston can shed light on this puzzle. The paper, by Columbia University economists Jimmy Charité and Raymond Fisman and Princeton University economist Ilyana Kuziemko argues that preferences for redistribution are affected by what the authors call “reference points.”

One of the insights of behavioral economics is loss aversion. In neoclassical economics, the utility gained from an extra dollar should be the same (but in the opposite direction) as the utility lost by losing a dollar. But research by behavioral economists and psychologists finds that losing a dollar causes a lot more disutility than the utility gained by gaining a dollar. This effect is why it feels much worse to lose $5 than to find a five-dollar bill on the ground.

Charité, Fisman, and Kuziemko present data that indicates loss aversion may explain why U.S. voters don’t redistribute more. To get at this problem, they run an experiment where they present respondents with a hypothetical situation in which two individuals receive money based on a coin flip. One person is given $15 and the other $5. The respondents are then asked to redistribute money between those two hypothetical people.

But the respondents are split into two groups and read slightly different prompts. The first group is told that the two hypothetical people receiving the money will only know the final amount of money they receive, not the money based on the coin flip. If the respondents redistribute $5 then they know the person who initially got $15 will only know in the end that the total amount received is $10.

In contrast, the second group is told that the two hypothetical people are aware of the money they received from the coin flip before redistribution. So again, if the respondents redistribute $5 then one of the people would know they had $15 but ended up with $10.

The results of the experiment show that these reference points actually change the level of redistribution quite a bit. In the first group, the respondents eliminate 94 percent of the income gap. But the group that has reference points and knows the recipients are aware of the redistribution only eliminates 77 percent of the gap. The level of redistribution is decreased by about 20 percent once reference points are included.

Of course, consideration of reference points isn’t the only factor explaining preferences for redistribution. Individuals might think that people deserve to keep a large portion of the money if it is based on skill or merit. Indeed, when the authors changed the reason for the distribution of income from a coin flip to SAT scores, the amount of redistribution declines to 56 percent. The decline in redistribution due to reference points is then about half of the decline caused by the distinction between luck and merit.

What’s so interesting about Charité, Fisman, and Kuziemko’s paper is that it indicates that the general public’s preferences for redistribution might be different from what is assumed in the classic optimal taxation research. Their research isn’t the first to point this out, but it provides more proof that the average person might not be a strict utilitarian. This in turn means that the classical economic model that undermines a fair bit of the conversation about the proper level of progressive taxation might be based on some flawed assumptions. The importance of that fact shouldn’t be lost on economists and policymakers.

This article is published in collaboration with Equitable Growth. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with Forum:Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Nick Bunker is a Policy Research Associate with the Washington Center for Equitable Growth.

Image: A woman holds a cluster of U.S. flags in Oakland, California August 13, 2013. REUTERS/Robert Galbraith.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Financial and Monetary SystemsEconomic Growth
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

The 'Great Wealth Transfer': What is it and how can women make the most of it?

Lena Haas

July 19, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Sign in
  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum