Equity, Diversity and Inclusion

The risks of large capital inflows

Nick Bunker
Policy Analyst, Washington Center for Equitable Growth
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Equity, Diversity and Inclusion?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Geo-economics is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Geo-economics

The “global savings glut” is a hot topic of conversation again among economists and policymakers courtesy of the recent debate between Ben Bernanke and Larry Summers over the sources of secular stagnation. In their debate, the former Federal Reserve chair and the former Clinton and Obama administration economic policy advisor, respectively, are focused in part on the sources of this world savings glut and in part on the roles those savings play in the lack of robust economic in the United States and other developed economies.

But it’s also important to think about what happens to all these global savings once they flow into other countries. A new working paper released last week highlights the costs and risks of large capital inflows on 69 middle- and high-income countries between 1975 and 2010,. That paper, released by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, digs into the effects of large inflows of capital on the performance of these economies. The authors of the paper, Gianluca Benigno of the London School of Economics, Nathan Converse of the Federal Reserve Board, and Luca Fornaro of Centre de Recerca en Economia Internacional, examine the high capital flows into these countries and find that their economic performances suffered suboptimal, to say the least.

The authors look at the trends in economic output and employment and find that while capital inflows for the entire country create a boom, the trends in output, employment, and productivity after the end of the inflows are lower than before the boom started. And, when they look just at high-income countries, they find that large capital inflows are often followed by “sudden stops,” when capital actually starts flowing out of the country and a recession is sparked.

Spain in the mid-2000s is emblematic of the effects of capital flows on economic output. Beginning with the creation of the Euro, massive capital inflows appear to have inflated a large housing and construction bubble in the country. When the inflows ended during the most recent financial crisis, the Spanish economy experienced quite a sudden drop.

Furthermore, Benigno, Converse, and Fornaro look at how capital inflows affect the allocation of resources in these economies between sectors. What they find is that capital inflows lead to a change in where capital goes within the economy. Specifically, the reallocation of capital is out of manufacturing and toward services that aren’t tradable, such as the construction industry in the case of Spain. Yet the reallocation of labor away from manufacturing toward services resulting from these capital flows only happens sometimes. When central banks increased capital reserves during periods of high capital inflows, their countries didn’t see labor moved out of manufacturing.

This shift could be responsible in part for the decline in productivity in economies that did not buffer their financial systems from high capital inflows. Manufacturing, especially in middle-income countries, has a higher level of productivity. The tradable sector, whose output is tradable internationally, tends to have higher productivity than the non-tradable sector, or domestic products and services.

Again, Spain is an obvious example. These capital inflows appear to have inflated a large housing and construction bubble in the country, which reduced total productivity growth, especially given the low productivity of the construction industry. This research is particularly relevant and important for policymakers moving forward as many of these episodes have happened over the past decade or so in developed countries in particular. As capital markets have been liberalized, large capital inflows into countries have become more common. Given the damage these large inflows can create, policymakers might want to think about the trade-offs from past liberalizations.

This article is published in collaboration with The Washington Center For Equitable Growth. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Nick Bunker is a Policy Analyst with the Washington Center for Equitable Growth.

Image: A man walks past buildings at the central business district of Singapore. REUTERS/Nicky Loh. 

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Equity, Diversity and InclusionGeo-Economics and Politics
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

More women are stepping into high-productivity service jobs, says the World Bank

David Elliott

July 18, 2024

3:37

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Sign in
  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum