What has experimental economics taught us?
Experimental economics is not really a new theory but a (still) relatively new method of studying the kind of questions that economists have studied for ages. But the addition of the experimental method to the economist’s toolbox is remarkable for at least two reasons.
First, even very recently some reasonably well-known economists have questioned the possibility that economics is to a considerable extent an experimental science, notwithstanding the fact that noted experimental economics proponents include Reinhard Selten (who shared the 1994 Nobel Prize with John Nash and John Harsanyi); (Vernon L. Smith, awarded the 2002 prize together with Daniel Kahneman; Elinor Ostrom; and Alvin E. Roth).
The experimental method has established itself firmly as a key tool in economists’ toolbox. New theories such as asymmetric information or efficient markets have been subjected to rigorous experimental laboratory testing. Maybe most surprisingly, macro-economic theories have also been subjected to such testing.
Second, the behavioural revolution in economics would not exist without the path-breaking contributions of experimental economics.
The same applies for recent academic theorising that has abandoned the presumption of “representative agents” (that is, the oversimplifying assumption that economic actors tend to be of one kind and motivated by self-interest).
A prominent test-bed has been the so-called guessing game used to explain the volatility of stock prices, which may depend not on fundamentals, but beliefs about beliefs (and actions) of others.
In their 2002 research, Antoni Bosch-Domenech and his colleagues identified the distribution of steps of reasoning among participants in guessing game experiments (and presumably markets) and inspired new models of interaction of agents with different depths of reasoning such as the cognitive hierarchy model of Colin F. Camerer and colleagues – a clever way of capturing the idea that some people think more steps ahead than others do.
Indeed, experimental economics results have brought about much new and interesting theorising.
Today, it is hard to think of any theory, or topic for that matter, which has not been studied experimentally. Individual decision-making, competitive and oligopolistic markets, matching markets, bargaining, auctions, political and other institutions (such as common pool resources or public good provision mechanisms), the internal dynamics of firms and other organisations, learning, social preferences, and macro-economic phenomena such as bubbles or bank runs all have been studied with experimental methods.
Insights from experimental economics inform policy design in many areas, from telecom auctions to markets mechanisms that match students and school or colleges, and interns with hospitals or high-court judges, to emissions trading schemes and various strategies to nudge people in directions that the policy maker finds welfare improving.
A important characteristic of experimental economics is its methodology which distinguishes it from other social sciences such as psychology. Experimental subjects are almost always paid on a performance basis. And it is generally not accepted to use deception.
Precise scripts are considered a must to facilitate replication. Decision-making is not studied as “as-if” proposition, but in laboratory representations of the problem studied. In such a representation subjects are typically instructed to enact a particular role such as buyer or seller, or that of a voter.
The different methodological practices are not quite as innocent as they may at first appear. That’s because the way one does an experiment is unbelievably important: different choices of particular design and implementation details can crucially affect results and can make the difference between accepting or rejecting a theory.
Experimental economists’ methodological practices have also influenced emerging experimental versions of finance, political science, philosophy, and has led to fruitful reflections in other social sciences. Increasingly, experimental economics has had to share the limelight with its close brethren behavioral economics and neuro-economics. In fact, many prominent experimental economists straddle these areas and then some.
Will economics become an experimental science? When economist Charles Plott asked this, it was already a rhetorical question as far as he was concerned; the proof of concept had long been provided.
By now the question of whether economics will become an experimental science is nothing but a silly question. It has to a considerable extent.
This article was originally published on The Conversation. Read the original article. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.
To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.
Author: Andreas Ortmann is Professor at UNSW Australia.
Image: A man walks in a building in Tokyo. REUTERS/Toru Hanai.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Agile Governance
Forum Stories newsletter
Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.
More on Economic GrowthSee all
Council on the Future of Growth and 2023-2024
December 20, 2024