Financial development can actually hinder growth at a certain point
Recent research suggests a point beyond which the benefits of financial development diminish, and further development can even hurt growth. Image: REUTERS/Daniel Munoz
Eilyn Lee Yin Chong
Graduate student, Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton UniversityAshoka Mody
Visiting Professor in International Economic Policy, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University.Francisco Varela Sandoval
Graduate student, Woodrow Wilson School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton UniversityAverage private credit-to-GDP – a commonly used measure of financial development – has increased steadily since 1960 (Figure 1). The credit-to-GDP ratio has been higher in advanced economies (AEs) than in emerging and developing economies (EMDEs), and the gap has increased since about 1990. Despite rapid financial sector growth in the advanced economies, GDP per capita growth remained almost unchanged (Figure 2). What role was rapid financial development playing if it did not help to raise growth in the advanced economies?
Figure 1. Average private credit-to-GDP by country group, 1960-2015
Figure 2 Average GDP per capita growth by country group, 1960-2015
Financial development and growth
The early empirical literature, starting with Goldsmith (1969), suggested that banks and financial markets allocate capital to the most productive endeavours; and the financial infrastructure accompanying credit reduces informational inefficiencies, such as moral hazard and adverse selection. Rajan and Zingales (1998) found that greater financial development promotes sectors that are not able to generate sufficient internal finance; Levine et al. (2000) went a step further and said that more finance increases an economy’s growth potential.
Recently, some scholars (e.g. Cecchetti and Kharroubi 2012) have told a more nuanced story. Financial development, they say, catalyses economic growth up to a point, beyond which more finance acts as a drag on growth. Several other authors have concluded that ‘too much finance’ can hurt growth (De Gregorio and Guidotti 1995, Gennaioli et al. 2012, Arcand et al. 2012, Dabla-Norris and Srivisal 2013). These authors argue that excessive finance sucks human capital away from the productive economy and, by creating macro and financial fragility, credit growth leads to bigger booms and busts, which leave countries ultimately worse off.
We take the Cecchetti and Kharroubi study as our starting point and ask: When and where did the adverse effect of finance on growth arise? And which way does the causality work? The simple scatter plots presented here tell the same story as the regressions they run with more control variables.
For 58 countries, from 1960 to 2015, Figure 3 plots five-year averages of credit-to-GDP and per capita GDP growth. As in Cecchetti and Kharroubi (2012), we observe some non-linearity. The turning point at which the marginal impact of finance on growth becomes negative – the so-called ‘too much finance’ effect – appears around a credit-to-GDP ratio of close to 95% (Chong and Varela Sandoval 2016).
Figure 3 Private credit-to-GDP ratio and growth
Figure 4 Private credit-to-GDP ratio and growth
Parsing the non-linearity
Figure 4 shows that when all countries are pooled by period, the finance-growth correlation is positive before 1990 and turns negative only after 1990. But this story hides a more complex reality. From Figure 5, we see a positive correlation between credit and growth for emerging and developing economies both before and after the 1990s; in contrast, the correlation is negative for the advanced economies even before 1990, but especially more negative after 1990. This suggests that two different sets of countries lie on either side of the non-linearity others have observed: emerging and developing economies with lower credit-to-GDP ratios benefit from more credit growth; advanced economies with higher credit-to-GDP ratios fare worse when credit increases, and this has been especially so since about 1990. But it is also the case that the negative relationship between credit and growth in the advanced economies begins even before the 90% credit-to-GDP threshold.
Figure 5 Private credit-to-GDP ratio and growth
Digging deeper into the advanced economy experience, the negative correlation between financial development and growth before 1990 existed mainly in the Eurozone countries; the post-1990 negative relationship between credit and growth is somewhat steeper in the Eurozone than in other advanced economies (Figure 6). Again, the more pronounced negative relationship between credit and growth in the Eurozone is not necessarily the result of higher credit-to-GDP ratio in the Eurozone countries compared to other advanced economies.
Figure 6 Private credit-to-GDP ratio and growth
What have we learned?
One interpretation of the data is that beyond about 90% of GDP, additional credit is largely counterproductive. The evidence certainly supports that inference. Especially after 1990, many advanced economies exceeded the 90% of GDP credit threshold, and more credit beyond that level is associated with lower growth. Also, emerging and developing economies have credit-to-GDP ratios below 90% of GDP and in those countries, more credit has been associated with higher growth.
The data are, however, also consistent with an alternative interpretation, one in which the causality runs the other way. Emerging and developing economies start from relatively low incomes and have, on average, higher growth potential. As they grow to realise that potential, the demand for finance leads to greater financial development. This would be in line with Joan Robinson’s view that “finance follows enterprise”.
For advanced countries, especially for Eurozone countries, the data show that GDP growth has tended to decline even before the 90% threshold has been reached. This was evident in the years before 1990, when credit in Eurozone countries did not exceed 90% of GDP.
The possibility exists, therefore, that in advanced economies – and more so in Eurozone economies – growth potential has been low and even falling. The fall in growth potential has created greater demand for finance. One mechanism by which this demand could arise has been proposed by Gennaioli et al. (2014). Because savings rates do not typically fall with slower growth, accumulated savings grow faster than GDP; hence, the wealth-to-GDP ratio increases – a proposition that Piketty and Zucman (2014) have documented. But this increasing wealth-to-GDP ratio creates a demand for finance as households seek to preserve their wealth. Households use the financial system to park their savings and borrow for consumption and buying new homes. The financial system grows even as economic growth continues to decline.
The observation that the negative relationship between finance and growth is steeper for the Eurozone relative to other advanced economies lends further support for this opposite causation. The Eurozone had a sharper slowdown in productivity growth in the 1990s and its population growth has also been lower than in other advanced economies. This would imply, as Piketty and Zucman confirm, that wealth-to-GDP ratios have risen particularly fast in the Eurozone countries.
Policymakers need to be aware of the possibility that causality runs in both directions. Countries that pursue financial development – and many emerging and developing economies will certainly want to do so – need to also continue to pursue productivity-enhancing reforms. Finance could prove an illusory source of growth in the absence of real entrepreneurship. Where growth potential falls, the financial sector may continue to increase in size to play its wealth-preserving role. This is an important function, but it also creates the potential for financial instability.
Our findings also have an implication for the presumption after the start of the Great Recession that resuming credit flows was essential for economic recovery. In the Eurozone, where the recovery has lagged, efforts to create a greater supply of credit have been an important policy focus. Recapitalisation of banks, in particular, has been seen as crucial to the recovery of both the banking system and the economy. But where in the past the financial sector served a primarily wealth-preserving function, and where substantial wealth has now been destroyed, pushing more credit in the hope that this will generate growth could be counterproductive. This attempt to push more credit into the economy would be particularly harmful if growth potential is low. The risk is that zombie banks will be propped up, and the costs of cleaning them up and closing them down will only increase over time.
References
Arcand, J-L, E Berkes and U Panizza (2012) “Too much finance?”, IMF Working Paper WP/12/161.
Cecchetti, S, and E Kharroubi (2012) “Reassessing the impact of finance on growth”, BIS Working Paper No 381, Bank for International Settlements.
Chong, E, and F Varela Sandoval (2016) “Does financial development help growth or hurt it, or neither?”, unpublished manuscript.
Dabla-Norris, E and N Srivisal (2013) “Revisiting the link between finance and macroeconomic volatility”, IMF Working Paper WP/13/29.
De Gregorio, J and P Guidotti (1995) “Financial development and economic growth”, World Development, 23(3): 433–448.
Gennaioli, N, A Shleifer, and R W Vishny (2014) “Finance and the preservation of wealth”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3): 1221–1254.
Gennaioli, N, A Shleifer, and R W Vishny (2012) “Neglected risks, financial innovation, and financial fragility”, Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3): 452-468.
Goldsmith, R W (1969), Financial structure and development, Yale University Press, New Haven.
International Monetary Fund (2015) “Euro area policies: Selected issues”, IMF Country Report No 15/205.
Levine, R, N Loayza, and T Beck (2000) “Financial intermediation and growth: Causality and causes”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(1): 31–77.
Levine, R (2005), “Finance and growth: Theory and evidence”, in P Aghion and S Durlauf (eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, 1(12): 865-934.
McKinnon, R I (1973), Money and capital in economic development, Brookings Institution, Washington DC.
Piketty, T, and G Zucman (2010) “Capital is back: Wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700-2010”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3): 1255-1310.
Rajan, R G, and L Zingales (1998) “Financial dependence and growth,” The American Economic Review, 88(3): 559-586.
Robinson, J (1952), “The generalization of the general theory”, The Rate of Interest and Other Essays. MacMillan, London.
Data sources
World Bank Global Financial Development Database (GFDD): Ratio of private credit-to-GDP, GDP per capita
58 countries:
26 emerging and developing economies: Argentina, Bangladesh, Brazil, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Egypt, India, Indonesia, Jordan, Kenya, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, the Philippines, Russia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Turkey, Venezuela, Vietnam, Zimbabwe
32 advanced economies: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Chile, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Singapore, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, United States.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Financial and Monetary Systems
Related topics:
The Agenda Weekly
A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda
You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.
More on Economic GrowthSee all
Harsh Vijay Singh and Attilio Di Battista
November 15, 2024