What is the 'ostrich effect' and how does it affect your personal finances?
Do we bury our heads in the sand of finance? Image: REUTERS/Mike Hutchings
Standard theories in economics predict that information is always valuable because it helps individuals make better decisions. In contrast, theories of rational inattention argue that individuals incur monetary or opportunity (time) costs of information acquisition that they compare with the expected benefits. Rational inattention has been used as an explanatory mechanism in recent theoretical work on asset pricing and macroeconomics. Woodford (2009), Reis (2006), Gabaix and Laibson (2002), and Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp (2009) are examples of this.
But people also seek out apparently useless information or avoid useful information (see Golman et al. 2016 for a survey of the research on this topic). Research into information-dependent utility argues that information also has a direct impact on utility that goes beyond information costs and benefits (Caplin and Leahy 2001, Golman and Loewenstein 2015, Kőszegi and Rabin 2009, Ely et al. 2015, Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp 2010).
What determines inattention?
There is, however, not much empirical evidence to answer this question. In particular, we still don't know whether theories of rational inattention or theories of information-dependent utility are more successful in explaining everyday behaviour.
In a recent paper, we present a large-scale empirical study of individual attention to checking, savings, and credit card accounts so we can better understanding the determinants of attention, and inform this theoretical work (Olafsson and Pagel 2018). We do this using data from a financial aggregation platform in Iceland that individuals use to check their bank accounts, but not to execute financial transactions. (Our work focuses solely on the determinants of paying attention, and not on its consequences, which was recently investigated by Carlin et al. 2017).^1
We use online account and smartphone app logins to measure individual attention. This method has previously been used by Sicherman et al. (2015), Karlsson et al. (2009), Gherzi et al. (2014) in studies of retirement portfolios. We also use high-frequency transaction-level data on income, spending, balances, and credit limits.
We ask the following questions:
>When and under what conditions do individuals pay attention to their financial accounts?
>Can our empirical findings be explained by 'rational' theories of inattention, that is, by direct information costs and benefits?
>To what extent is inattention not 'rational' but 'selective' – that is, driven by information-dependent utility?^2
Selective inattention
We find that inattention is selective rather than rational, and that information-dependent utility generating ‘ostrich effects’ (avoiding bad news) and anticipatory utility (an increase in current utility from looking forward to future consumption) are of first-order importance for individual attention to financial accounts.
Figure 1 illustrates this. It shows a positive correlation between bank account balances and logins, and a jump when balances go from negative to positive in the raw data. Anecdotal evidence from online media suggests that it is common to be afraid to check bank account balances.
Figure 1 Average login by binned checking account balances, including only individuals who have negative and positive checking account balances at some point in time
Our data allow us to compare individuals within their own histories.^3 In other words, we consider people with low or high cash holdings, or small or large overdrafts, relative to their average amount of cash holdings and overdrafts. This meant that we can obtain results that do not reflect differences across individuals. Moreover, we control for all individual characteristics and all regular week or holiday patterns, as well as overall trends. We thus look at individuals when they have relatively high or low cash holdings or overdrafts, and find a number of patterns. Individual attention:
>increases with the arrival of perfectly predictable income,
>decreases with spending and increases with savings,
>increases with cash holdings and liquidity,
>decreases with individual overdrafts, especially of intermediate amounts, and
>jumps discontinuously when checking account balances change from negative to positive.
Interpreting the findings
To interpret this, we consider how a rationally inattentive agent, who is subject to information costs and benefits but does not experience information-dependent utility, would behave. We compare our empirical evidence to four rational hypotheses. These argue that individuals will log in:
>irrespective of their transactions – because they either know everything or nothing about what is going on in their accounts,
>for transaction verification,
>to budget or to plan spending, or
>when opportunity costs are low (that is, individuals have not many other things to do, or who have low time costs).
We argue that these rational theories of inattention are inconsistent with our empirical findings:
>Logging in irrespective of transactions can be ruled out. Perfectly predictable income payments caused an increase in logins. Thus, individuals could not be fully certain or uncertain about the transactions in their accounts.
>Transaction verification did not seem to be the main motivation for logging in. For instance, we did not find a larger login response on paydays with many other transactions, even though other transactions should increase the need for transaction verification.
>Login response on paydays was higher when cash holdings and liquidity were high. This would be inconsistent with hypothesis 2 as well as hypothesis 3, because individuals should have cared more about budgeting when cash holdings and liquidity were low.
>We find a negative relationship between logins and spending (especially time-consuming spending, such as restaurant meals and home improvement), which suggests that spending could be used to measure opportunity costs. But the response of logins on paydays is unaffected by concurrent spending.
Attention to bank and retirement accounts
There are three important differences between attention to retirement accounts, as analysed by Karlsson et al. (2009), and our context.
We know that individuals can improve their financial standing by paying more attention to their accounts (Carlin et al. 2017, Stango and Zinman 2014, Medina 2016), but we do not know whether investors have any skill in stock-picking or market timing. This implies that attention to bank accounts would be more beneficial than attention to portfolios.
Uncertainty about bank account balances should be much lower than uncertainty about portfolios. This would make inattention more difficult to rationalise theoretically, and so it should be more surprising for checking accounts.
We discover selective attention in an everyday activity for a broad and representative sample of the population. This implies that selective inattention is a more widespread phenomenon than previous studies suggest.
Therefore we argue that our results make a general case for information-dependent utility models generating ostrich effects and anticipatory utility. To bolster this argument, we investigate how far the most widely-applied information-dependent utility model, developed by Kőszegi and Rabin (2006, 2007, 2009), can reconcile and formalise intuitions consistent with our empirical evidence - that is, that individuals incur substantial fees by being inattentive, but they check their accounts more often when they have received income and hold more cash. We find that the model of Kőszegi and Rabin (2009) generates some of our empirical findings, but not others.
The assumptions of rational inattention in macroeconomic models would generate different aggregate dynamics if inattention were selective, as our findings suggest, instead of rational. We show this formally using a simple Lucas (1979) tree model in the spirit of the time-variant attention model of Andrei and Hasler (2014).
Because any agent with a prudent utility function finds consumption smoothing more beneficial at low wealth levels, a rationally inattentive agent should pay more attention – in other words, smooth consumption at a higher frequency – when there is an adverse consumption shock. We assume that a selectively inattentive agent would do the opposite. We in turn show that the model’s predictions about the risky, risk-free, and equity premium’s return and volatility are substantially affected if we assume selective, as opposed to rational, inattention.
Applications of selective inattention
Our findings also contribute to other researchers’ findings on information costs (Abel et al. 2013, Alvarez et al. 2012, Huang and Liu 2007, Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp 2009, and Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp 2010, for example). This study, alongside Carlin et al.’s (2017) investigation of the causal effect of paying attention to personal finances, implies that individuals are sometimes willing to pay not to receive information. Therefore information costs are time-variant in non-trivial ways, and sometimes effectively negative.
Furthermore, because individuals in dire financial standings do not pay attention, making their situation worse, our findings are useful for research on poverty traps (see Azariadis and Stachurski 2005 for a literature survey) and on poverty and cognitive function (Mani et al. 2013, Carvalho et al. 2016).
Finally, our findings are important for policy prescriptions or (field) experimental interventions. In these cases, it would be important to take into account that inattention is selective rather than rational (see DellaVigna 2009 for a literature survey).
Author’s note: This project has received funding from Danish Council for Independent Research, under grant agreement no 6165-00020. We are highly indebted to Meniga’s Analytics Team for providing and helping with the data.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
The Digital Economy
The Agenda Weekly
A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda
You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.
More on Economic GrowthSee all
Sonia Ben Jaafar
November 22, 2024