Financial and Monetary Systems

The risks of interbank market fragmentation

European Union flags fly outside the European Commission headquarters in Brussels June 15, 2005. The EU budget battle and salvaging the proposed constitution will top the summit agenda for the 25-nation bloc when it meets on June 16-17 at its Brussels headquarters. UNICS REUTERS/Thierry Roge  THR/CCK - RTREFSU

Interbank market fragmentation can have significant welfare costs. Image: REUTERS/Thierry Roge

Silvia Gabrieli

By affecting the funding capacity of banks, interbank market fragmentation can hinder the smooth transmission of monetary policy and thus impair the provision of credit to the real economy. This column examines the fragmentation of the euro area interbank market in 2011-15, and finds that the size and quality of banks’ exposures to peripheral countries impaired banks’ access to, and increased the price paid for, interbank funding. This important channel of fragmentation risk was stopped by the ECB’s announcement of possible Outright Monetary Transactions in secondary government bonds markets.

Interbank market fragmentation can have significant welfare costs – by affecting the funding capacity of banks, it can hinder the smooth transmission of monetary policy and thus impair the provision of credit to the real economy. In the euro area, fragmentation has been fuelled by the sovereign-bank nexus, with banks in Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain (the ‘GIIPS’ countries) being affected by their own governments’ debt problems and vice-versa (Fahri and Tirole 2018). The need to turn financial fragmentation around and safeguard the singleness of euro area monetary policy has been an important reason for unconventional monetary interventions. Going to the heart of the drivers of euro area fragmentation, one can ask the following questions:

Does the funding cost differential between peripheral and non-peripheral banks reflect the poor quality of banks’ assets (classic credit risk) or the loss of sovereign support in case of failure (because of the loss of the explicit or implicit guarantee of sovereign bailout)? How do lending conditions in the interbank market interact with monetary policy?

Following the euro area sovereign debt crisis, a strand of research has focused on the international transmission of sovereign risk to the real economy through the bank lending channel (Altavilla et al. 2018, Popov and van Horen 2015). The increased riskiness of sovereign debt holdings can lead to a reduction in lending through a tightening of bank funding. In a recent paper (Gabrieli and Labonne 2018), we show that such a tightening was indeed at work in 2011-15, through a higher cost and a reduced availability of interbank liquidity. We find that a credit risk (i.e. exposure-driven) effect was at play besides a pure sovereign-dependence effect. Both GIIPS and non-GIIPS banks suffered from fragmentation risk.

Sources of fragmentation of the euro area interbank market

The interbank market is an informal market where banks exchange liquidity, mostly uncollateralised and at very short maturities. It allows banks to co-insure against liquidity shocks (as in Allen and Gale 2000) and to minimise the opportunity cost of holding excess reserves. The smooth functioning of this market is crucial for the implementation of monetary policy and for financial stability alike – liquidity tensions have proved to be a powerful channel for the transmission of shocks across borders during recent financial crises. This is particularly true in the euro area because of the importance of cross-border financial flows.

Once bank-specific risk is taken into account, access to the market and interbank rates should not differ significantly depending on the location of banks’ headquarters. That is, a well-functioning interbank market should be integrated. Throughout 2011-15, however, banks headquartered in peripheral countries on average paid higher rates (volume-weighted) than non-peripheral banks (see Figure 1). The difference was especially large in December 2011, before the Eurosystem’s first three-year liquidity refinancing operation, and before the August 2012 announcement that the ECB might undertake outright open market operations in secondary government bonds markets.

Figure 1 Weekly average interest rate in the euro area overnight interbank market for GIIPS and non-GIIPS banks

 GIIPS = Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, Cyprus. The vertical lines define three monetary policy periods: Period 1 (Pre-OMT): July 2011 - July 2012; Period 2 (OMT): August 2012 - June 2014; Period 3 (Targeted Long-Term Refinancing Operations, or TLTRO): July 2014 - December 2015. Averages of interest rates are volume-weighted.
Image: Gabrieli and Labonne (2018)

In theory, one can distinguish two sources of euro area fragmentation:

First, domestic sovereigns are primarily responsible for bailing banks out in case of failure. Bank funding could thus be negatively affected by pure home-country sovereign risk because of the lost guarantee of sovereign support. This is the sovereign-based source of fragmentation. Second, banks are overly exposed to their domestic economy, both via private sector and via sovereign assets. The size and quality of their exposures can increase concerns about counter party risk and profitability, and hence affect banks’ funding capacity. This is the balance sheet (credit risk) source of fragmentation. Indeed, when contagion is very likely, as in 2011-15, lenders in the interbank market could react to country risk rather than to idiosyncratic counter party risk.

Disentangling the sources of fragmentation in the context of unconventional monetary policy

To disentangle the two sources of fragmentation, we combine lender-borrower (bank-to-bank) unsecured loan data estimated from TARGET2 payments1 in 2011-15 with detailed supervisory information disclosed since 2011 by the European Banking Authority (EBA) on the capital positions and exposures of 115 European banks.2 For each loan, we observe the lending and the borrowing bank, the date, volume, and interest rate of the loan. Through EBA data, we observe the cross-border and cross-sector (sovereign, corporate, retail) composition of banks’ exposures. We use this information to construct several measures of each bank’s GIIPS-related credit risk. Through this unique dataset, we can study the impact of sovereign and balance sheet risk, as measured by the size and quality of exposures to GIIPS, on the probability of finding a lender in the interbank market and on loan interest rates.

We test the predictions of a simple model of participation in the interbank market which takes into account the interaction between interbank lending and central bank liquidity provision. We expect interbank rates (access) to increase (decrease) in a bank individual default probability and in the probability of default of its sovereign. Before the ECB’s announcement of Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) on sovereign debt securities, we expect interbank rates (market access) to increase (decrease) the larger the size of, and the riskier, the bank exposures to GIIPS assets. After the OMT, we expect lenders to revaluate the riskiness of GIIPS assets. This could alleviate balance sheet-based and sovereign-based fragmentation alike.

Empirically, we disentangle the two potential channels for fragmentation by comparing borrowing conditions across GIIPS and non-GIIPS (e.g. Finnish, German, or French) banks. We look at the effect of the size and quality of their GIIPS exposures on interbank lending terms, after taking into account other bank-specific risk characteristics (size, rating, and capital ratio) and country-specific risk factors (e.g. sovereign CDS). We make sure that the effects are not driven by changes in borrower demand or by other shocks to banks’ balance sheets. Furthermore, we estimate our model on the sample of non-GIIPS banks only (64 out of a total of 115 European banks represented in the EBA sample) to get a neater separation of the effect due to large exposures to GIIPS assets from the effect due to the dependence to a risky sovereign. Throughout the period of the analysis, between 80% and 90% of non-GIIPS banks are exposed to GIIPS countries, mostly through sovereign asset holdings.

The OMT reduced both sources of interbank fragmentation

Our analysis shows that banks headquartered in GIIPS countries are not the only ones to suffer from interbank fragmentation. Non-GIIPS banks exposed to GIIPS suffer as well, and the larger and the riskier their GIIPS exposures, the more they suffer. These effects vary through time.

We highlight three findings.

First, we find that, all other things equal, high non-performing loan (NPL) ratios on GIIPS assets hindered access of non-peripheral banks to the interbank market during the entire sample period. Higher NPL ratios on GIIPS assets decreased the probability of finding a lender. Second, from mid-2011 until the OMT, a non-peripheral bank paid more for interbank loans the larger its exposures to GIIPS sovereigns. Specifically, an increase in the share of GIIPS sovereign exposures by 1 percentage point raised interest rate spreads by 1.3 basis points. This represents 13% of the average spread paid by non-GIIPS borrowers in this period. Third, the OMT was successful in closing this channel of sovereign risk transmission. That is, after the OMT announcement, we find no significant differences in interbank rates depending on banks’ exposures to GIIPS. Moreover, the selection effect due to high NPL on GIIPS assets, while still significant, becomes much weaker. Regarding sovereign-dependence risk, while before the OMT we measure positive home-country risk premia in interbank spreads (e.g. for Spanish, Italian, and French banks), these premia fall and even turn to discounts afterwards (see Figure 2). After the OMT, when we observe fragmentation, it is mainly driven by idiosyncratic balance sheet risk.

Figure 2 Home country risk premia for Spanish, Italian and French banks

 Home country risk premia are average country trends in interbank spreads computed from interest rate estimations (from the borrower-country fixed effects interacted with time). They provide information on pure home country sovereign risk of the borrowers. More details about the computation of the risk premia and their time series plots (including confidence intervals) are available in the paper.
Image: Gabrieli and Labonne (2018)

Overall, the OMT affected both sources of fragmentation – it reduced the country premia paid by GIIPS borrowers, but it also affected lenders’ pricing of counterparty credit risk.

Authors’ note: The views expressed in this column are those of the authors only and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Eurosystem, the Banque de France, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston or other parts of the Federal Reserve System.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

Financial and Monetary Systems

Related topics:
Financial and Monetary SystemsEquity, Diversity and Inclusion
Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Financial and Monetary Systems is affecting economies, industries and global issues
World Economic Forum logo

Forum Stories newsletter

Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.

Subscribe today

How digital platforms and AI are empowering individual investors

Rishi Kapoor

December 20, 2024

How investing in connectivity and digital infrastructure can be a catalyst for inclusion and empowering people

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum