Financial and Monetary Systems

Why governments saving during the boom may have consequences for the rest of the world

German, French and EU flags flutter in front of the Reichstag building ahead of a meeting with Western Balkans leaders, at the Chancellery in Berlin, Germany, April 29, 2019. REUTERS/Annegret Hilse - RC1AC7C22300

Keynes proposes imposing taxes on capital outflows to discourage large current account surpluses. Image: REUTERS/Annegret Hilse

Luca Fornaro
Junior Researcher , CREI
Federica Romei
Assistant Professor, Stockholm School of Economics
Share:
Our Impact
What's the World Economic Forum doing to accelerate action on Financial and Monetary Systems?
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Banking and Capital Markets is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
Stay up to date:

Inclusive Growth Framework

In the last few years, Germany, the Netherlands, and other countries have controversially been running fiscal and current account surpluses. These policy stances seem to make sense from a national perspective – economic growth in these countries has been robust, and thus their governments are following the Keynesian notion that the "boom, not the slump, is the right time for austerity at the Treasury" (Keynes, 1937).

But running a tight fiscal policy stance against a background of low interest rates and weak global growth might produce strong contractionary spillovers toward the rest of the world (Krugman 2013, Setser 2019).

A model of a global liquidity trap

In a recent paper (Fornaro and Romei 2019), we propose a framework to think formally about this debate. We model a multi-country world in which the presence of financial frictions limits the global supply of safe assets, and depresses interest rates. If global rates are low enough, the world ends up being stuck in a global liquidity trap. Monetary policy is constrained by the zero lower bound on the interest rate, and so this is a situation in which a significant fraction of the world economy operates below full employment.

Our global liquidity trap has two key features:

Asymmetry: There are country-specific shocks and so, during a global liquidity trap, not all countries need to be constrained by the zero lower bound and experience a recession. The model thus captures situations such as the asymmetric recovery that has characterised advanced countries after the 2008 global crisis (Figure 1).

Persistence: A global liquidity trap is a persistent event that is expected to last for a long time. Hence, during a global liquidity trap, countries experiencing a boom in the present anticipate that they might fall into a recessionary liquidity trap in the future.1

Figure 1 Policy rates and real gross domestic product per capita

a) GDP per capita

Image: Fornaro and Romei (2019)

b) Policy rates

Image: Fornaro and Romei (2019)

The top panel highlights the relatively fast recoveries from the 2009 recession experienced by the US and Japan, and the slow recovery in the Euro area and in the UK. The bottom panel shows the exceptionally low interest rates after 2008. The figure also shows the heterogeneity between fast-recovering core euro area countries, captured by Germany, and the stagnation experienced by peripheral euro area countries, captured by Spain.

Prudential policies and the paradox of global thrift

We show that, during a global liquidity trap, domestically oriented governments have an incentive to implement countercyclical fiscal policies. Put simply, the reason is that reducing public debt during booms creates space for fiscal expansions during future recessions.

A similar motivation leads national governments to intervene on the financial markets to impose countercyclical macroprudential regulations (Farhi and Werning 2016, Korinek and Simsek 2016). Improving the private sector’s financial position during booms, the logic is, helps sustaining aggregate demand during future busts.

Interestingly, in a financially integrated world this prudential approach to fiscal and financial policies has an international counterpart. In fact, prudential fiscal and financial policies lead to an increase in national savings, and in the current account surpluses of booming countries.

But what happens if prudential policies are implemented on a global scale? Our fundamental insight is that the world might fall prey of a paradox of global thrift, which is essentially an international and policy-induced version of Keynes' paradox of thrift (Keynes 1933).

By stimulating national savings and current account surpluses, governments in countries undergoing a period of robust economic performance increase the global supply of savings, depressing aggregate demand around the world. Central banks in countries stuck in a liquidity trap cannot respond to the drop in global demand by lowering their policy rate. Therefore the implementation of prudential current account policies by booming countries aggravates the recession in countries experiencing a liquidity trap. And so prudential policies might backfire and, paradoxically, lead to a fall in global output and welfare.

International cooperation and Keynes’ Plan of 1941

This result sounds a note of caution on the use of prudential policies as stabilisation tools. More precisely, our framework highlights three factors that make a paradox of global thrift more likely to occur.

First, the contractionary spillovers from prudential policies are stronger when the ability of the world economy to supply assets is low, and so a paradox of global thrift is more likely to happen when the global supply of assets is scarce and inelastic.

Have you read?

Second, in our model the contractionary spillovers from prudential policies arise during periods of weak global demand, that is when the zero lower bound constrains monetary policy. Worryingly, scarce supply of safe assets, weak demand and low interest rates are salient features of the current state of the global economy (Caballero at al. 2016, Eggertsson et al. 2016).

Third, it's the lack of international cooperation gives rise to a paradox of global thrift in our model. Key to our results, indeed, is the fact that governments in booming countries do not take into account the negative spillovers that their policies might impose on the rest of the world. Our analysis, which resonates with the logic of Keynes' Plan of 1941, thus suggests that, when global aggregate demand is scarce, international cooperation is needed to ensure that fiscal and financial policy interventions by booming countries do not impart excessive negative spillovers on the rest of the world.2 For instance, in his 1941 plan, Keynes proposed discouraging excessively large current account surpluses by imposing simple taxes on capital outflows. It might be time to consider this type of policy.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:
Financial and Monetary SystemsHealth and Healthcare SystemsEconomic Growth
Share:
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

The 'Great Wealth Transfer': What is it and how can women make the most of it?

Lena Haas

July 19, 2024

About Us

Events

Media

Partners & Members

  • Sign in
  • Join Us

Language Editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

© 2024 World Economic Forum