How can developing economies recover from the pandemic?
Many developing economies are in signifcant debt due to COVID-19. Image: UNSPLASH/Visual Stories || Micheile
- Global government debt soared in the pandemic-induced global recession, tempting some to rely on post-pandemic growth and inflation to reduce debt burdens.
- Evidence suggests, however, that medium-term growth prospects are dimming and inflation helps reduce debt burdens only under particular circumstances.
- Some developing economies may need to resort to debt default to restore fiscal sustainability, with the associated heavy economic and political cost.
- The global community can help by coordinating prompt and efficient debt relief and restructuring.
In last year’s COVID-19-induced global recession, global government debt surged in its largest single-year increase on record. Globally, government debt stood at a five-decade record of 97% of GDP and, in emerging market and developing economies (EMDEs), at a three-decade record of 63% of GDP in 2020. This comes on top of soaring private external debt, which often hits the public balance sheets in a crisis, not to mention considerable strains on EMDE banking systems.
How will this debt eventually be resolved?
EMDEs may find it tempting to rely on the post-pandemic growth and inflation rebound to reduce debt burdens (Bianchi et al. 2020). The global economy has rebounded from last years’ recession in the strongest recovery from any global recession in eight decades. This has been accompanied by a remarkably early and fast rebound in global inflation after an unusually muted decline during last year’s global recession (Figure 1; Ha et al. 2021).
Figure 1 Inflation
Note: CPI refers to consumer price index. Year-on-year group median inflation for 81 countries, of which 31 are advanced economies and 50 are EMDEs.
But to what extent can EMDE policymakers rely on inflation and growth for reducing government debt burdens in a lasting manner? Our recent study (Kose et al. 2021a) sheds light on this question, as well as two others: What role can default play in returning debt to manageable levels? How can the global community help lessen debt burdens?
Inflation…
Unexpected inflation can erode real debt burdens if it raises nominal incomes faster than nominal interest rates. Inflation, typically combined with financial repression, has been credited with debt reduction in advanced economies after WWII and in Latin America in the 1980s and 1990s (Reinhart and Sbrancia 2015).
However, inflation has drawbacks as a debt reduction strategy, especially for EMDEs. First, the subsequent disinflation that would be needed to return to low and stable inflation would be economically costly.
Second, inflation is unlikely to reduce real debt burdens in a lasting manner when the share of short-term debt or foreign currency-denominated debt is large. In the median EMDE, foreign-currency denominated government debt accounted for 42% of government debt in 2019. If a large share of debt is short-term and needs to be rolled over, interest rates on newly issued debt will rise with inflation because investors demand higher interest rates in compensation. If a large share of debt is foreign currency-denominated, the depreciation that typically accompanies inflation raises debt service burdens. Historically, in periods when EMDE debt service on external debt exceeds 22% of exports – a level EMDEs are now again approaching for the first time in three decades – the rate of debt default exceeded 20% (Figure 2). Challenges also arise when government debt is predominantly external as foreign creditors can more readily escape domestic financial repression.
Figure 2
Note: Debt service is an average for 123 EMDEs; exports refer to exports of goods and services. Shaded area indicates years in which more than 20 percent of countries (of a sample of up to 193 in 2020) were in default.
Third, as high inflation becomes entrenched in expectations, it is reflected in nominal interest rates and no longer reduces the real value of debt. While financial repression may prevent a rise in interest rates to match inflation, it is a policy that distorts economic activity and is difficult to sustain after decades of open financial markets and capital accounts. As a result, surprise inflation would be most useful for a one-off reduction in high debt. If high debt is the result of persistent spending pressures or revenue weaknesses – as it has been over the past decade – a bout of surprise inflation cannot reduce real debt burdens in a lasting manner. Moreover, persistently high inflation risks undermining the hard-won credibility that some EMDE central banks have achieved over the past three decades (Ha et al. 2019).
… growth…
Historically, some advanced economies and EMDEs were able to reduce debt by achieving growth rates in excess of interest rates. This includes US debt reduction after WWII as well as debt reductions for at least two years in 50 EMDEs since the 1980s (Reinhart et al. 2015, Baldacci et al. 2012). In fact, most of the time, including over the 2010s, growth rates have been sufficiently high to exceed the interest cost of government debt in advanced economies and EMDEs alike (Kose et al. 2020). Nevertheless, interest spending in EMDEs rose steadily over the 2010s (Figure 3).
Figure 3
Note: Unweighted averages of long-term nominal interest rates for up to 84 EMDEs and interest spending in percent of GDP for up to 150 EMDEs. Net interest payments are computed as a difference between primary balances and fiscal balances.
However, caution is warranted. First, historically, growth alone has typically not been sufficient to lower debt over extended periods. Periods of high debt – when a debt reduction might be most desirable – have not been accompanied, or followed, by high growth (Reinhart et al. 2012). Being able to borrow may be good for growth, but a hangover of high debt is not.
Second, periods of interest rates below growth rates can come to a swift end. Countries with larger debt levels tend to have higher interest rate-growth differentials and these deteriorate faster in response to shocks (Lian et al. 2020). Interest rate-growth differentials that were significantly lower in years just preceding debt booms turned significantly higher in debt booms (Kose et al. 2021b).
Third, past episodes of debt reduction through rapid growth typically followed periods in which debt rose quickly after one-off shocks such as wars (Reinhart et al. 2015). This may parallel the debt build-up during COVID-19. However, the debt surge last year followed a steady debt build-up during the 2010s when broader spending pressures and revenue weaknesses, rather than temporary shocks, raised debt.
Fourth, the generally favourable interest rate-growth differentials over the last five decades may dissipate over the next decade as growth prospects dim. Even before the pandemic struck, the global economy was undergoing a decade of slowing productivity growth accompanied by weak investment. The additional damage from the pandemic may further steepen the slowdown in potential output growth (Bartolomew and Diggle 2021).
What's the World Economic Forum doing about diversity, equity and inclusion?
… or default?
If both inflation and growth fail as mechanisms to reduce debt burdens in a lasting manner, highly indebted EMDEs may eventually need to resort to debt default or restructuring. Over the past 200 years, the average advanced economy defaulted more than twice on external debt and the average EMDE more than four times (Reinhart and Rogoff 2009). Among 64 large economies, there were at least 68 episodes of domestic debt defaults (Reinhart and Rogoff 2011). These domestic debt defaults were typically accompanied by galloping inflation and significantly worse macroeconomic outcomes.
While external debt default and restructuring may offer immediate debt relief, they also impose long-term costs. Bond yields are higher to compensate for default risk; international capital market access is curtailed; and financial stability is at risk if government debt holdings by domestic banks are large. Domestic debt default also imposes long-term costs. Inflation expectations can become de-anchored and government debt rollover can get more difficult or more expensive.
In addition, future debt restructurings may be more challenging than past ones. The creditor base for EMDE debt has fragmented over the past two decades (Horn et al. 2021). In low-income countries, a growing share of debt is held on non-concessional terms and by non-traditional creditors including China. This may increase incentives to settle for shallow debt restructurings but, in the past, these have proven temporary (Graf von Lucker et al. 2021).
How can the global community help?
On occasion, through well-coordinated umbrella initiatives, the global community has been able to help restore fiscal sustainability faster and more efficiently than through normal court processes. Historical examples that coordinated large numbers of debtors and creditors, include the Multilateral Debt Relief Initiative from 2005, the HIPC Initiative from 1996, the Baker Plan from 1989-94, and the Paris Club established in 1956.
More recently, new initiatives have sprung up that have parallels with past umbrella debt relief initiatives. These have included the G20’s Common Framework, among others. But if the post-pandemic EMDE debt crisis becomes systemic, much more will need to be done.
Editor’s note: The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this column are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries they represent.
References
Baldacci, E, S Gupta, and C Mulas-Granados (2012), “Reassessing the Fiscal Mix for Successful Debt Reduction”, Economic Policy 27(71): 365–406.
Bartholomew, L and P Diggle (2021), “The Lasting Impact of the COVID Crisis on Economic Potential,” VoxEU.org, 21 September.
Bianchi, F, R Faccini, and L Melosi (2020), “How to Pay for the (Pandemic) War,” VoxEU.org, 13 May.
Graf von Luckner, C, J Meyer, C M Reinhart, C Trebesch (2021), “External Sovereign Debt Restructurings: Delay and Replay,” VoxEU.org, 30 March.
Ha, J, M A Kose, and F Ohnsorge (2019), “The Great Disinflation in Emerging and Developing Economies,” VoxEU.org, 11 April.
Ha, J, M A Kose and F Ohnsorge (2021), “One-Stop Source for Inflation: Introducing a New Database,” VoxEU.org, 17 August.
Horn, S, C M Reinhart, and C Trebesch (2021), “Coping With Disasters: Lessons from Two Centuries of International Response,” VoxEU.org, 20 March.
Kose, M A, P Nagle, F Ohnsorge, and N Sugawara (2020), Global Waves of Debt, World Bank.
Kose, M A, F Ohnsorge, C M Reinhart, and K S Rogoff (2021), “The Aftermath of Debt Surges,” CEPR Discussion Paper 16537.
Kose, M A, F Ohnsorge, and N Sugawara (2021), “A Mountain of Debt: Navigating the Legacy of the Pandemic”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 9800.
Kose, M A, S Kurlat, F Ohnsorge, and N Sugawara (2017), “A Cross-Country Database of Fiscal Space,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 8157.
Lian, W, A Presbitero, and U Wiriadinata (2020), “Public Debt and r-g At Risk,” IMF Working Paper 20/137.
Reinhart, C M and K S Rogoff (2009), This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, Princeton University Press.
Reinhart, C M and K S Rogoff (2011), “The Forgotten History of Domestic Debt,” The Economic Journal 121(May): 319–350.
Reinhart, C M and M Sbrancia (2015), “The Liquidation of Government Debt,” Economic Policy 30(82): 291–333.
Reinhart, C M, V Reinhart, and K Rogoff (2012), “Public Debt Overhangs: Advanced-Economy Episodes Since 1800,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 26(3): 69-86.
Reinhart, C M, V Reinhart, and K Rogoff (2015), “Dealing with Debt,” Journal of International Economics 96(S1): S43-S55.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Social Protection
The Agenda Weekly
A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda
You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.
More on Financial and Monetary SystemsSee all
Filipe Beato and Charlie Markham
November 13, 2024