Is shadow banking good for the economy?
Shadow banking, what is it good for? At the epicentre of the global financial crisis, shadow banking has become the focus of intense regulatory scrutiny. All reform proposals implicitly take a stance on its economic value.
According to the prevailing regulatory arbitrage and neglected risks views, it doesn’t have any – shadow banking is about evading capital requirements, exploiting “too big to fail” and marketing risky securities as safe to unwitting investors. The right response is to bring shadow banking into the regulatory and supervisory regime that covers insured banks.
A third view, the liquidity transformation view, is different. It says that shadow banking adds value by creating money-like liquid securities from risky illiquid assets (Gorton and Metrick 2010). While this process is inherently unstable, simply shutting it down risks damaging liquidity provision to the real economy.
The liquidity transformation view confronts us with a real trade-off between financial stability and economic growth. In a recent paper (Moreira and Savov 2014) we formalize this trade-off within a dynamic macroeconomic model, and draw its implications for regulatory reform.
People want money
The last two decades have seen a dramatic rise in worldwide demand for safe and liquid securities, or money for short. These securities enable the large volume of transactions that course through the modern economy. Yet the supply of truly safe (typically government-backed) assets needed to back them has not kept up. Shadow banking has been making up the difference via money market funds, asset-backed commercial paper, and dealer repurchase agreements.
The key feature of these instruments is that they function just as well as traditional money (think of bank deposits or short-term government obligations) during quiet times, but they abruptly lose their liquidity at the first sign of trouble. Of course, it would be better to have fully stable liquidity, but in a world of limited good collateral, shadow banking may well be the next-best alternative.
Shadow banking booms and busts
In our paper, we show that the liquidity expansion enabled by shadow banking leads to a lower cost of capital for firms, greater investment, and a higher level of economic growth. Moreover, during a shadow banking boom, the economy moves up the risk-return frontier, funding riskier but more productive investments. Over time, this process builds up fragility.
At the peak of a shadow banking boom, even a modest shock can set off a cascade of adverse events. Faced with increased uncertainty, investors are no longer willing to hold shadow banking securities whose liquidity could easily evaporate. Shadow banking shuts down. The flight to safety forces the financial sector to de-lever as liquidity creation now requires more collateral. The liquidity crunch forces discount rates up and asset prices down. The instability of prices drives up margins, leading to a downward spiral that exacerbates the collateral shortage and the liquidity crunch. The end result is that capital investment falls and the economy enters a deep recession.
The problem with shadow banking then is that while it makes the good times better, it also makes the bad times worse. In the language of economics, shadow banking imposes a negative externality on the rest of the economy. During the boom, individual institutions have little incentive to take into account the impact of their actions on the severity of the bust. Shadow banking allows them to fund riskier assets more cheaply, but doing so decreases the economy’s supply of good collateral when times get rough.
Implications for policy
This collateral externality represents a sound rationale for government intervention. Our work shows that the precise nature of the intervention is important, as it needs to strike the right balance between curtailing excessive risk-taking and preserving liquidity provision.
At the heart of a shadow banking bust is an acute shortage of good collateral resulting from the risky investments made during the boom and the margin spirals that unfold in the bust. The central bank can alleviate this shortage by buying up risky assets and providing safe ones, as the Fed did in the autumn of 2008. A well-timed intervention can arrest the financial collapse and stabilize the economy.
Interestingly, a maturity extension programme like Operation Twist can be counterproductive. The reason is that long-duration safe assets like Treasury bonds tend to appreciate in a crisis. This means that they serve as a hedge when combined with risky assets on bank balance sheets. Treasury bills and excess reserves do not have this property. This type of programme cannot be judged by its effect on long-term Treasury yields, as it tends to lower them even as it is making the financial sector more constrained, not less.
More recently, the Fed has been implementing a reverse repurchase programme that allows it to provide liquidity directly to non-banks. The Fed sells bonds from its balance sheet to money market funds in exchange for cash (excess reserves), then repurchases the bonds on the following day with a bit of interest. Until now, this process has taken place in the private repo market.
The attraction of the reverse repo programme is that it provides a stable source of liquidity to a wide variety of institutions. At the same time, it has important limitations that have not received attention. The Fed’s bond holdings are very safe, which means that private intermediaries are left holding riskier ones. As a result, reverse repo might crowd out fully safe private intermediation like Treasury-backed repo, and actually crowd in riskier shadow banking activity.
A reverse repo programme backed by lower-quality collateral (or no collateral at all) would not have this downside, though it could expose the Fed to losses. Such a programme would be closer to the realm of fiscal policy, and might best be left to the Treasury. For example, the Treasury could issue floating-rate debt. The benefits of doing so should be weighed against distortions arising from increased taxation.
The bottom line
Above all, our point is that when it comes to reforming the shadow banking system, there are serious trade-offs. Six years after the collapse of Lehman, these trade-offs need to be understood so that we can grapple with the question: By how much should we lower the height of the boom to ensure a softer landing in the bust?
Published in collaboration with Vox.
Authors: Alan Moreira is an assistant professor of finance in the School of Management, Yale University. Alexi Savov is an assistant professor of finance at the Stern School of Business, New York University.
Image: A shadow is cast on the Bank of England in London December 20, 2013. REUTERS/Suzanne Plunkett
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Banking and Capital Markets
Related topics:
The Agenda Weekly
A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda
You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.
More on Financial and Monetary SystemsSee all
Matthew Cox and Luka Lightfoot
November 22, 2024