Financial and Monetary Systems

Are big cities always more expensive?

David E. Weinstein
Professor, Center for Japanese Economy and Business

It’s a common perception that big cities are expensive places to live. Big cities like New York are typically reported to have a cost of living more than double that of small cities like Des Moines, Iowa with nominal wages that are only 40% higher on average. Why then isn’t there a massive exodus from large cities into small ones?

New evidence

A common explanation is that larger cities offer better amenities (Glaeser and Kerr 2008). In our forthcoming paper (Handbury and Weinstein 2014), we suggest a much simpler explanation for this discrepancy – the standard price indexes are wrong. We study the prices of barcoded grocery items sold across cities in the US and find that almost all of the variation in prices across cities can be attributed to flaws in the data used to make spatial price comparisons.

Our results suggest that, when measured correctly, there is in fact very little variation in prices across cities!

We choose to focus our analysis on barcoded grocery items because one needs to worry much less about unobserved quality variation when comparing the price of, say, a 12-ounce can of Coca-Cola across cities than when comparing the price of a two-bedroom apartment. Even in this set of products, conventional price indexes that are widely used in economic studies and wage setting guidelines suggest massive variation in prices across cities. For instance, it is not uncommon for these indexes to register that consumers in some cities pay over 75% more for their groceries than consumers in other cities.
Biases in current methodology

One of the problems with these conventional indexes is that they compare the prices of similar, but not identical, goods. The first problem with this methodology stems from the fact that there is a wide variation in the prices of items like eggs, cheese, and milk depending on the variety chosen. For example, the price of a half-gallon of whole milk can easily vary by over 100% within the same store depending on the brand. As a result, simply comparing the price of, say, milk across locations can be very misleading if different types are chosen in different locations. These price comparisons misleadingly indicate prices are higher in large cities if richer consumers tend to prefer more expensive varieties of the same category of good, since richer people tend to congregate in large cities.

We call this first problem ‘product heterogeneity bias’ because it arises when consumers think of similar products very differently and as a result are willing to pay very different prices for different varieties. A second important source of bias comes from not carefully controlling for where goods are bought.

For example, it is not a surprise that richer people shop in nicer stores that provide a better shopping experience. Since consumers know that they typically pay more when they shop in a nicer store, a price comparison should not compare prices in a low-end grocery store with prices in a high-end one. Instead, one should control for store heterogeneity and compare the prices of identical goods purchased in the same type of store.

We can see the effect of correcting for these biases in Figure 1, where we plot the food price indexes for 49 US cities. As we can see from the plot, while there is a clear upward association between average city prices and a price index constructed using the conventional methodology with Nielsen scanner data, the positive association almost vanishes entirely when we correct for the product and store heterogeneity biases. Moreover, one can also see that virtually all of the variance in prices across cities disappears once we control for heterogeneity biases. On average, the prices of groceries are almost identical in all cities in the US.

Figure 1. Adjusted and conventional food price indexes

Note: Using Nielsen HomeScan data we see that there is a positive relationship between city size and food prices when we construct the index using conventional methodologies. The relationship disappears when we adjust for product and store heterogeneity biases

A second major problem with price indexes used to compare price levels across space is that they make no adjustment for the availability of goods in different locations. Existing price indexes compare the prices of a commonly available set of goods, but large cities typically have many more varieties than small ones. For example, we estimate that there are four times more varieties of grocery items in New York than in small cities like Des Moines. This result helps explain an intuitive feeling big city residents often feel in small cities – it’s hard to find many of the goods that they want to buy. Indeed, the tremendous diversity of products available in large cities like New York is one of their great attractions.

How should we think about the way the availability of varieties affects prices? Economists have long known that consumers should be indifferent between not having a variety and having that variety priced sufficiently high, so that no one is willing to buy it. Thus, when conventional price indexes ignore variety differences, they are effectively dropping the set of goods that are particularly expensive in small cities. In our paper, we develop a methodology for correcting for this bias as well.

Figure 2. The exact price index in US cities

Note: The ‘epi’ or exact price index properly adjusts price comparisons, product, and store heterogeneity bias, as well as variety availability bias.

As one can see in Figure 2, correcting for both the heterogeneity and variety biases, results in a complete reversal in the conventional wisdom – grocery prices are actually lower in large cities!

This result stems from the fact that commonly available varieties are priced at approximately the same price in all locations and consumers can choose from more varieties in large cities.
Concluding remarks

These results have important implications for understanding international variations in purchasing price parity (PPP) as well. If estimates of average prices (i.e., PPP) are so sensitive to comparing identical goods and adjusting for variety availability, then it stands to reason that these forces are also likely to be extremely important when comparing price levels in rich and poor countries. Maybe life is much worse in poorer locations than these indexes suggest.

References

Glaeser E and W Kerr (2008), “Industrial agglomeration and entrepreneurship”, VoxEU.org, 26 November

Handbury J and D E Weinstein (2014), “Goods prices and availability in cities”, The Review of Economic Studies.

Published in collaboration with VoxEU

Authors: Jessie Handbury is the Assistant Professor at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. David E. Weinstein is Carl S. Shoup Professor of the Japanese Economy and Associate Director of Research at the Center for Japanese Economy and Business.

Image: Pedestrians walk along the High Line park in New York, June 12, 2013. REUTERS.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

Financial and Monetary Systems

Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Financial and Monetary Systems is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

Climate adaptation finance: The challenge for institutional investors and commercial banks

Matthew Cox and Luka Lightfoot

November 22, 2024

What is the gig economy and what's the deal for gig workers?

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum