How will the second machine age affect jobs?
In a famous book, the two economists Erik Brynjolfsson and Andrew McAfee from MIT describe how recent advances in artificial intelligence are changing our lives: driverless cars, drones for package delivery, computer programs to diagnose illnesses, intelligent pattern recognition software that replaces lawyers, 3D printing, etc (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014). They call these developments the ‘second machine age’.
In this column, I want to discuss two hypotheses of how the second machine age may affect the world we live in.
- Hypothesis 1. Robots will bring manufacturing back to the rich countries as machines are replacing workers and the cost of labour will not matter much.
- Hypothesis 2. Intelligent machines will replace smart people rather than increase the demand for skills (capital bias rather than skill bias technical change) and as a result the relative price for skills (the skill premium) will decline.
The revival of manufacturing in rich economies
Let me start with the first hypothesis. Anecdotal evidence of reshoring (the relocation of activity back from the low-wage countries to the high-wage countries) is mounting. Apple is shifting back some of the activity from Foxconn China to Silicon Valley in California; Airtex Design Group is shifting part of its textile production from China back to the US (see New York Times 2013). In a recent survey by the management consultancy PricewaterhouseCoopers among 384 firms in the Eurozone, two-thirds said they had reshored some activities during the past 12 months and 50% plan to do so in the next 12 months.
But can we see these developments in the data? In Figure 1, I look at the offshoring of production of rich economies to the low-wage countries (Asia, Eastern Europe, Brazil, and Mexico). The data were collected by Timmer (2012) from the World Input-Output Database. Offshoring is measured by the ratio of imported intermediates from low-wage countries to total intermediates used in the respective country. The data clearly show no sign of reshoring. The opposite is the case. In the Great Recession of 2008 we see a drop in offshoring activity in the US and Europe. But the activity quickly rebounded, increasing faster than before the crisis.
Figure 1. Offshoring to low-wage countries
Figure 2. Offshoring regions
Figure 2, however, shows a shift in the pattern of offshoring of European firms away from eastern Europe (including Russia and Ukraine) to Asia, in particular to China. Since 2005, Germany, France, and Italy have made Asia an important destination for their offshoring activity.
Physical capital rather than human capital
Let me turn now to the second hypothesis. Acemoglu and Autor (2011) argue that the second machine age represents a skill-biased technology. Technology and skills are complements and thus technology requires ever more skills. As the demand for skills rises, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers (the college premium) will rise as well. The rise in the skill premium will be even steeper if a country does not expand the supply of skills fast enough. In their book The Race between Education and Technology, Goldin and Katz (2009) argue that since 1980 education in the US has stopped advancing fast enough to meet the pace of technological change, and this led to a steep rise in inequality between skilled and unskilled workers in the US in the 1980s and 1990s.
How has the skill premium evolved in Europe? Figures 3 and 4 report the evidence. The data were collected by Timmer (2012) from the World Input-Output Database. Except for the US and more recently Germany (since 2001), the skill premium between tertiary education and secondary education on the one hand, and between tertiary education and primary education on the other, is declining in all Western countries (Figure 4).
Why is this happening? There are two possible explanations for the decline in the skill premium in Europe.
- First, a reverse Goldin and Katz effect may be at work in Europe. Advances in education may have been faster than the pace of technical change.
Indeed, Figure 5 shows that education has advanced fast in most of Europe since the turn of the century, while it has advanced slowly in the US and Germany. In Austria, the share of people with an academic degree increased 2.5 fold between 1996 and 2012, in the UK and Italy it almost doubled, in Spain it increased by 70%, and in France by 60%. The US and Germany have seen a modest increase in the share of the population with a tertiary education of about 25% in the last 17 years. The data suggest that education policy in Europe was far too aggressive given the demand for skills.
Figure 3. Hourly wages by skill level
Figure 4. The skill premium of tertiary education
Note: There is a dip in the graphs in 2003 for some countries due to a break in the underlying data.
Source: WIOD Socioeconomic Accounts (July 2014).
Figure 5. Tertiary education of 25–64-year-olds (in percent of population)
Note: tertiary education: ISCED categories 5 and 6
Source: OECD, Education at a glance 2014.
- A second explanation is that the second machine age represents a capital-bias technology that requires ever less human capital as physical capital replaces human capital.
Technology and skills are substitutes and thus intelligent machines are replacing educated people such as lawyers, doctors, professors, and journalists. As the demand for skills declines, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers will decline as well. Do we have evidence that the technology is indeed of a capital bias nature? Three pieces of evidence are available:
- The decline in the skill premium in Europe;
- The global decline of the labour share in GDP since 1980; and
- The rise in skill unemployment, in particular among the young.
The decline in the skill premium
In addition to the fast expansion of the supply in education in Europe, the demand for skills may have slowed because physical capital is replacing educated workers. It is difficult to separate the supply side from the demand side effect on the skill premium. But the US is a case in point here. Education has been advancing only modestly in the US since the turn of the century, which should have put upward pressure on the skill premium. Nonetheless, the trend in the skill premium since 1999 has been almost flat (see Figure 4) suggesting that capital-bias technology has been driving this trend in the US. In the 1980s and 1990s, the slow expansion of education in the US led to a steep rise in the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers.
A more nuanced version of skill-biased technical change is the polarisation hypothesis according to which computers will increase the demand for both the highest-skilled jobs (professional and managerial) and the lowest-skilled jobs (personal services) with a decline in jobs in the middle (routine office jobs). Middle-skilled jobs are driven out by computers replacing routine labour, while computers fail in the more complex jobs at the top and the bottom of the skill distribution. The decline in the wage gap between high-skilled and medium-skilled workers in all western countries except the US and Germany does not give strong support for this hypothesis, however.
The decline of the labour share in GDP
It used to be the case that about 70% of income went to labour income and 30% to capital income. Since the 1980s, the share of income going to labour has declined in all rich countries. It is now at about 58% of GDP. In a recent paper, Karabarbounis and Neiman (2014) show that 50% of this decline is due to lower costs of information technology allowing firms to replace workers with the cheaper physical capital.
The rise in skill unemployment
Skill unemployment is on the rise in the US and the UK, where it doubled between 2000 and 2012, and in Spain and Italy, where it tripled in the same period. In Germany and France we do not see a rise in skill unemployment. The doubling of academic unemployment between 2000 and 2012 and the modest increase in the skill premium in the US, in spite of the slow expansion of education, suggest that capital bias technology is driving this outcome. In Germany, skill unemployment is low and did not increase between 2000 and 2012 precisely because education was advancing slowly there.
Are we fighting the wrong battle? Is the rapid expansion of education as an answer to the challenges of globalisation the wrong way to go? Will we see an excess supply of human capital in the next decade that earns penny wages? It may well be that the ‘war for talent’ and the scarcity of human capital is an issue of the past.
References
Acemoglu, D and D Autor, D (2011), “Skills, tasks and technology: Implications for employment and earnings”, Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Brynjolfsson, E and A McAfee (2014), The second machine age: Work, progress, and prosperity in a time of brilliant technologies, New York,NY: WW Norton & Company.
Goldin, C D and L F Katz (2009), The race between education and technology, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Karabarbounis, L and B Neiman (2014), “The global decline of the labor share”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 61, 103.
Timmer, M P (ed). (2012), The world input-output database (WIOD): Contents, sources and methods, WIOD Working Paper Number 10.
Published in collaboration with VoxEU
Author: Dalia Marin Dalia Marin holds the Chair in International Economics at the University of Munich and joined Bruegel as a research fellow in October 2007.
Image: Machines in a car manufacturing plant. REUTERS
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Innovation
Related topics:
Forum Stories newsletter
Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.
More on Financial and Monetary SystemsSee all
Rishi Kapoor
December 20, 2024