What makes us expect price rises?
Guillermo Cruces
Deputy Director, Center for Distributive, Labor and Social Studies (CEDLAS), Universidad Nacional de La PlataExpectations about macroeconomic variables play an important role in economic theory and policymaking. Household inflation expectations, in particular, are key to understand consumption and investment decisions, and ultimately, the impact of monetary policies. Although central banks have a natural desire to influence expectations, there is no consensus on how household expectations are formed or what the best way to affect them is (see Bernanke 2007, Bachmann et al. 2012, Coibion and Gorodnichenko 2013, and Armantier et al. 2014).
When measured using surveys, household inflation expectations tend to be much more heterogeneous than those of professional forecasters (Ranyard et al. 2008, Armantier et al. 2013). As an illustration, Figure 1 provides a comparison of households’ and experts’ expectations for the US and Argentina, the two countries in our study (see Nishiguchi et al. 2014 for similar evidence from Japan). Two main explanations have been given in the economics literature for this degree of dispersion in household expectations. Some authors attribute it to rational inattention, according to which individuals only partly incorporate information on topics such as inflation statistics, because acquiring that information is costly (Mankiw et al. 2003, Carroll 2003). This explanation is particularly convincing in contexts of low inflation like the US, where the potential financial cost of ignoring inflation is negligible for most households. Other authors argue that, in forming inflation expectations, individuals use information derived from their personal experience as consumers, which can be both diverse and inaccurate (Bruine de Bruin et al. 2011, Malmendier and Nagel 2013, Madeira and Zafar forthcoming). These explanations are hard to distinguish empirically because they are not mutually exclusive. Individuals may choose to be rationally inattentive and, at the same time, use their personal shopping experiences as a low-cost source of information about price changes.
Figure 1. Households’ and professional forecasters’ inflation expectations for 2013, US and Argentina
Note: Expected inflation for the period 1 January to 31 December 2013, reported in December 2012.
Sources: University of Michigan’s Survey of Consumers, December 2012 (household survey, US, N=502), Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s Survey of Professional Forecasters, fourth quarter of 2012 (professional forecasters, US, N=48), WP Public Opinion Survey (household survey, Argentina, N=777; see Cavallo et al. 2014 for details) and LatinFocus Consensus Forecast, January 2013 (professional forecasters, Argentina, N=16).
New evidence from survey experiments
In recent work (Cavallo et al. 2014), we present evidence from a series of survey experiments specifically designed to disentangle some of these effects. We randomly provided subjects with information related to past inflation, such as inflation statistics and the historical prices of specific supermarket products. On the basis of that experimental variation, we use a Bayesian learning model to infer how much weight subjects assign to a given piece of information relative to their prior beliefs about past inflation. Our methodology allows us to distinguish between spurious and genuine learning. In order to assess the role of the rational inattention model, we conducted similar experiments in a context of low inflation – the US, with an average annual inflation rate of 1.8% in the five years prior to our study – and in a context of high inflation – Argentina, where the average annual inflation rate over the same time period was around 22.5%.1
Households update their beliefs, especially in a low-inflation context
Our results indicate that information related to past inflation has a major impact on inflation expectations. We find that, when confronted with information about past inflation that is different from their priors, individuals will assign a weight of 50% to 80% to the new data to update their beliefs. This happens both when we provide information about aggregate inflation statistics and when we provide information about the historical prices of a few individual supermarket products. This evidence is consistent with the existence of largely inattentive consumers who learn from new information.
Furthermore, the results across countries suggest this inattention is rational. Relative to her prior belief, an individual in a low-inflation context assigns a weight of roughly 85% to the information on recent inflation statistics, whereas an individual in a high-inflation context assigns a weight of roughly 50%. The differences are similar when comparing the weights assigned to information about supermarket prices rather than inflation statistics. The fact that learning rates were 70% higher in the low-inflation context is consistent with the rational inattention model, which predicts that individuals in a context of higher inflation are more informed because the cost of misperceiving inflation is greater.
Inflation statistics vs. prices of familiar products
In one of our treatment arms, we provided individuals with information on inflation statistics and, simultaneously, with information on historical prices for a handful of supermarket products. Subjects still assigned significant weight to the prices of specific products – even a higher weight than that assigned to inflation statistics. In other words, subjects were more prone to incorporating information about the price changes of a few familiar products, such as bread and milk, than to statistics on the price changes of thousands of products. One possible interpretation, still consistent with rational inattention, is that it is less costly for individuals to incorporate information on individual prices because they are easier to understand.
Memories can be misleading
Given that inflation statistics are costly to interpret, individuals may substitute inflation statistics for their memories about price changes at retail stores. To better understand how past shopping experiences affect inflation expectations, we conducted a consumer intercept survey experiment at a supermarket chain in Argentina. We recorded consumers’ purchases by scanning the supermarket receipts of participants, which were linked to data on the actual historical prices of those same products at the same store. We also asked respondents to recall historical prices for a random set of items that they had just purchased, which allowed us to generate exogenous variations in the salience of their own price memories. We find evidence that individuals use their own memories of price changes for specific products when forming inflation expectations. However, their memories are orthogonal to the actual price changes experienced by the products recently bought by the subjects. Far from correcting a representativeness bias in aggregate inflation statistics, the use of price memories as inputs in the formation of inflation expectations seems to induce significant errors in inflation expectations.
Concluding remarks
Our findings are relevant for recent debates on central bank transparency and communication strategies. Central banks will often try to use information to affect household inflation expectations. At the time of writing, for example, Japan’s central bank is eagerly trying to increase household inflation expectations (see Baldwin and Gros 2013), while high-inflation countries such as Argentina and Venezuela are desperately trying to reduce them. Our evidence suggests that, in addition to the dissemination of aggregate statistics, central banks have an additional policy margin that consists of communicating how objective, precise, and representative their statistics are. For example, the ECB and the French statistical agency have made notable efforts to create online tools to convey this information and the way it is collected and processed in a user-friendly way. Moreover, in addition to publishing aggregate annual inflation rates, statistical agencies could provide tables with historical prices for individual products similar to the ones in our experiments, selecting sets of widely known products with average price changes that replicate the aggregate rate.
Published in collaboration with VoxEU
Author: Alberto Cavallo is Assistant Professor of Applied Economics at MIT Sloan. Guillermo Crucas is Deputy Director of the Center for Distributive, Labor and Social Studies (CEDLAS) at Universidad Nacional de La Plata. Ricardo Perez-Truglia is Postdoctoral Researcher in Economcs at Microsoft Research New England.
Image: A shopping cart is pushed down the aisle in this photo illustration. REUTERS/Srdjan Zivulovic
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Banking and Capital Markets
Related topics:
The Agenda Weekly
A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda
You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.
More on Financial and Monetary SystemsSee all
Matthew Cox and Luka Lightfoot
November 22, 2024