Education and Skills

Should universities be responsible for the students’ loans?

Nick Bunker
Policy Analyst, Washington Center for Equitable Growth

As the amount of student debt in the United States increases and concerns about students default proliferate, policymakers are considering many options for reducing the debt of those seriously in need of help. One such idea is “risk-sharing.” Under this proposed policy, if a student defaults on his or her loan then the university he or she graduated from is responsible for paying part of the loan.

How would colleges and universities respond to a policy like this? A new paper by Temple University economist Douglas A. Webber tries to answer that question, at least in part. One potential consequence of risk-sharing would be an increase costs for schools. If they’re on the hook for some loans then the marginal cost of admitting a student would go up.

Webber uses data from the Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System, or IPEDS, from the U.S. Department of Education. The data cover the 1987-1988 school year to the 2010-2011 school year, but not every year for every school in the data. He then uses the data to create a model that estimates the effects of risk-sharing.

The amount of increase in tuitions varies quite a bit depending upon the kind of higher-education institution. Colleges and universities that have higher default rates and students with more loans and larger amounts of loans would see the largest increases in tuition. And because those kinds of institutions are concentrated in the for-profit sector, tuition at for-profit should would jump up the most.

Webber’s model tuition at for-profit schools predicts an increase of 1 to 2 percent under the less-stringent form of risk-sharing or by 3 to 4 percent under the more-stringent risk-sharing arrangement. The increases for other types of schools would be much lower. Student-debt from the for-profit sector would decrease by $13 million per institution per year under the less-stringent arrangement and $80 million under the stronger form.

But these calculations assume that institutions would do nothing to reduce the default rate of their students. As Webber points out, this is hopefully an unreasonable assumption about the behavior of schools. History shows it to be unrealistic as universities and colleges seem to have cut default rates in response to a 1991 law change punishing institutions with high default rates.

What happens to Webber’s calculations once we assume schools will try to reduce default rates? Assuming a 10 percent drop in default rates, the increases in tuition would be smaller across all types of colleges and universities. And the decrease in student debt would be considerable larger, at about $42 million to $130 million, depending on the level of risk-sharing.

The plan does have some drawbacks. In particular, Webber finds that risk-sharing would result in a decline in the number of students attending and graduating from institutions of higher education. He points out that a reduction in college graduates might not be worrying because the higher prices will signal to some potential students that college might not be an economically sound investment for them.

But this assumes that the students turned away by higher prices would necessarily not be a good fit for college. We know that isn’t true. Or the savings from fewer defaults and loans could be plowed back into government budgets to reduce tuition prices. Unfortunately, that would only work for public colleges or universities.

So while risk-shifting seems like a policy idea with some merit, we have to be aware of how it might interact with other potential problems in the higher-education system. The unintended consequences are always in the details.

This article is published in collaboration with Washington Center for Equitable Growth. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Nick Bunker is a Policy Analyst with the Washington Center for Equitable Growth.

Image: Profile of students taking their seats for the diploma ceremony at Harvard University in Cambridge REUTERS/Brian Snyder

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

Education

Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Education is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

Why younger generations need critical thinking, fact-checking and media verification to stay safe online

Agustina Callegari and Adeline Hulin

October 31, 2024

Skills for the future: 4 ways to help workers transition to the digital economy

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum