Economic Growth

Lessons for Greece on forcible currency conversions

Carmen M. Reinhart
Minos A. Zombanakis Professor of the International Financial System, Harvard Kennedy School of Government

Abandoning a pegged exchange rate or violating an exchange rate band is not a black swan event. Over the sweep of history, governments have reneged on their exchange rate commitments fairly regularly. Exits from hard pegs, such as those associated with the gold standard of an earlier era, are less frequent and possibly associated with a higher reputational cost. Transitioning from one currency to another (a shift in what constitutes legal tender) is less frequent still, but not unheard of, as many newly formed nation states supplanted the currency of their coloniser with one of their own.[1] Apart from these transitions in the context of nation building, there are comparatively fewer cases of full-fledged currency conversions.

Many of the modern currency transitions were associated with either the creation of the euro or with unilateral decisions by nations who wanted to adopt someone else’s currency de jure as their sole legal tender. In those instances, the euro and US dollar emerged as the anchor currencies of choice. Examples of the former include Malta (2008), and Lithuania (2015), while Panama (1904) and Ecuador (1999) illustrate the latter. Since it was founded in 1847, Liberia relied on the US dollar as its legal tender almost exclusively. Long civil wars and their associated fiscal toll, however, necessitated the creation of its own currency. Because this transition occurred over the course of a very protracted and often chaotic conflict, it does not offer a particularly instructive roadmap as to what to expect if Greece was to exit the euro.

There is, however, a much longer list of countries that (for a variety of reasons) ended up de facto highly dollarised (or euroised). In these countries, despite the existence of a domestic currency, a significant share of bank deposits and loans are denominated in a foreign currency. US dollars or euros are widely accepted for payment and everyday transactions; larger ticket items (such as housing) are often priced in the foreign currency. A number of these countries have tried to ‘undo’ this dollarisation. Their approach has ranged from the gradualist and ‘market friendly’ to more abrupt forcible conversions – usually in the midst of economic crisis. The economic outcomes of these de-dollarisation efforts have also varied over both the short and medium term.

Undoing domestic ‘dollarisation’

To identify those cases where the reversal of deposit dollarisation was large and lasting, in a recent paper my co-authors and I searched for all those episodes where the ratio of foreign currency deposits to broad money satisfied the three conditions (Reinhart et al. 2014). These conditions were that the ratio:

(a) Experienced a decline of at least 20 percentage points;

(b) Settled at a level below 20% immediately following the decline; and

(c) Remained below 20% until the end of the sample period.

Only four of the 85 countries with data on foreign currency deposits met the three criteria during the period 1980-2001: Israel, Mexico, Pakistan and Poland. Argentina post-2002 is the fifth case (see Figure 1). Bottom line – de-dollarisation is rare.

Figure 1. Foreign currency deposits as a share of broad money, Argentina’s December 2001- December 2002 corralito and forcible conversion

150710-currency conversion argentina pesa voxeu chart

Source: Banco Central de la Argentina.
Notes: When the deposits were converted at the rate of 1.4 pesos per 1 US dollar, the black market exchange rates (there were more than one at this time) were in the 2+ pesos to 1 US dollar range. Thus there is a haircut for depositors.

Israel and Poland – both in the more gradual, and the market friendly approach – appear as the only two cases on record of large and lasting reversals of deposit dollarisation that had minimal side effects on financial intermediation, output losses, and capital flight.2 In both cases the de-dollarisation started almost at the same time as the authorities embarked on a (eventually successful) disinflation program centred around a strong exchange rate anchor. Along with this, the domestic financial system offered assets with alternative forms of indexation (Israel), or with very high real interest rates (Poland). De-dollarisation in these gradualist experiences took place as the countries exited from economic crisis – this feature also limits their relevance to the challenges now facing Greece.

There are five episodes over 1982-2002 where forcible conversion of foreign currency deposits and loans into local currency in domestic banks takes place amid deep economic crises. These de-dollarisation measures were introduced alongside capital and exchange controls, default on external debts and internal arrears, deposit freezes, and, in some cases, bank holidays and nationalisation. These episodes include (in reverse chronological order): Argentina in January 2002; Argentina in December 1989; Peru in July 1985; Bolivia in November 1982; and Mexico in August 1982.3

We document selective indicators (capital flight, parallel market premia, real per capita GDP growth, and bank deposits as a share of GDP to assess the state of financial intermediation) around the time the measures are implemented. To be clear, the analysis is descriptive and does not directly assess the impact of the measures per se on the economy. The endogeneity of capital controls (to which these conversion measures are intimately related) is recognised in much of the literature (see Drazen and Bartolini 1997, Cardoso and Goldfajn 1998, and Reinhart and Rogoff 2004). The exercise is informative on the various questions regarding the duration of the measures.

The episodes

Table 1 presents estimates of capital flight (as a share of GDP) in the year of the conversion and the years before and after.4 As noted, the compulsory conversion of foreign currency deposits into local currency is prompted by the rapidly deteriorating economic environment. Capital flight with or without bank runs, was a catalyst to governments and central banks who neither have the hard currency on hand to meet the escalating withdrawals, nor have the ability to print dollars themselves. Capital flight, especially when compared to tranquil periods (not shown here) is exceptionally high during these episodes, as well as immediately before and after. It is also evident from Table 1 that it is difficult to conclude that the conversions (and the capital controls that accompanied these) were especially successful in stopping the leakage.5 The leakages were in part driven by expectations of future exchange rate instability, as evidenced in the next to last column of Table 1, which shows the peaks in the parallel market premia during the conversion window.

Table 1. Episodes of involuntary conversion: Capital flight estimates, parallel market premia and capital controls

Sources: International Monetary Fund, Balance of Payments Statistics and International Financial Statistics, Pick’s World Currency Report, various issues, Chang, Claessens, and Cumby (1997), Savastano (1996), and Reinhart (2004), Reinhart and Rogoff (2004).
Notes: Capital flight is estimated as the sum of net private capital inflows plus net errors and omissions in the balance of payments accounts. These are, on the whole lower bound estimates, as they do not factor in mis-invoicing of trade. Estimates of export under-invoicing and import over-invoicing add significantly to the figures reported here during these periods.
1Since the conversion occurs at the very start of the year (and the deposit freeze had already been in effect since December 2001), we treat 2001 as the year of the conversion and 2002 as the year after.
2This measure of capital flight is estimated to have reached a peak of 13.4% of GDP in 1980.
3As this measure does not fully capture the external US dollar deposits of residents, it severely under-estimates Mexican capital flight. According to a US General Accounting Office (1997) study, these deposit withdrawals brought the foreign exchange clearing system “to the edge of a breakdown.”

Two further observations on the final column of Table 1:

  • The capital and exchange controls were in place for an extended period of time – usually longer than what was initially announced; and
  • Because of the persistence of capital flight and the revealed preference of domestic residents to hold their savings in assets other than domestic currency bank deposits, foreign currency deposits were re-allowed by the authorities (reversing their earlier decision to de-dollarise) in all five episodes.

Figure 2 illustrates the policy reversal in the cases of Bolivia and Peru.

Figure 2. Failed de-dollarisation attempts

To reiterate, not all the countries that introduced severe restrictions on the availability of dollar deposits managed to lower the deposit-dollarisation ratio on a sustained basis. Bolivia and Peru adopted measures similar to those of Mexico in the early 1980s but, after some years of extreme macroeconomic instability that took them to the brink of hyperinflation, both countries eventually re-allowed foreign currency deposits, and have since remained highly dollarised despite their remarkable success in reducing inflation (see Figure 2).

Even in the countries where the restrictions on dollar deposits have, thus far, led to a lasting decline of deposit dollarisation, the costs from de-dollarisation were far from trivial. In Mexico, capital flight more than doubled and bank credit to the private sector fell by almost one-half in the two years that followed the forced conversion of dollar deposits, and the inflation and growth performance remained dismal for several years (see Dornbusch and Werner 1994).6

Growth, currency conversions, and default

Table 2 shows real per capita GDP growth in the years before, during, and after the deposit conversion. Recalling that the periods in question are characterised by a general lack of confidence on the part of the public at large, a loss of access to international credit by both public and private sectors, high inflation (in one case, hyperinflation), uneven efforts at fiscal adjustment or austerity, and in some cases adverse external shocks (via terms of trade, international interest rates, or both) – it is hardly a surprise that growth implodes in the windows around the conversions.

The brief discussion in the last column of Table 2 also highlights that the sovereign external defaults were not resolved quickly. While not shown here (see Reinhart and Trebesch 2014), in all five episodes, the exit from default involved debt relief, which ultimately took the form of haircuts on principal.

Table 2. Real per capita GDP growth (%) and sovereign default around episodes of forcible currency conversions

Sources: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, Savastano (1996), Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), Reinhart et al (2013), Standard and Poor’s.
Notes: These episodes are considered as sovereign defaults on domestic debt (given the unfavourable terms imposed on the depositors). In the midst of an economic crisis (and debt restructuring), in 1999, Pakistan froze foreign currency bank deposits in an effort to stem capital flight. This was not on par with the other episodes of conversions, so we do not include it here.
1Since the conversion occurs at the very start of the year (and the deposit freeze had already been in effect since December 2001), we treat 2001 as the year of the conversion and 2002 as the year after.
2In 1983 the output collapse is -11.5%.

Financial disintermediation

In light of the aforementioned discussion on capital flight, parallel market premia, and the dearth of growth, a contraction in intermediation during these crises is not a surprise. The magnitude of the implosion shown in Table 3, however, surpasses what one may have anticipated. It is reminiscent of Diaz Alejandro’s (1985) characterisation of a process…

“…where domestic financial intermediation flourished and then collapsed.”

Table 3. Episodes of involuntary conversion of bank deposits and financial dis-intermediation (bank deposits as % of GDP)

Source: Banco Central de la Argentina, International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics and World Economic Outlook.

Concluding remarks

In a scenario where Greece rapidly reaches a meaningful debt reduction agreement with its creditors and the ECB provides support to restore the confidence of Greek depositors in what is at present an insolvent banking sector, Grexit need not happen. If the road ahead leads to the drachma, the episodes described here highlight that such a road is likely to be long and winding.

References

Chang, P H, S Claessens and R E Cumby (1997) “Conceptual and methodological issues in the measurement of capital flight”, International Journal of Finance & Economics, 2(2): 101-119.

Diaz-Alejandro, C (1985) “Good-bye financial repression, hello financial crash”, Journal of Development Economics, 19(1): 1-24.

Bartolini, L and A Drazen (1997) “Capital-account liberalization as a signal”, The American Economic Review, 87(1): 138-54.

Reinhart, Carmen  M. (2015), Testimony before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, Subcommittee on National Security and International Trade and Finance, 25 June.

Reinhart, C M and K S Rogoff (2004) “Serial default and the ‘paradox’ of rich to poor capital flows”,The American Economic Review, 94(2): 53-59.

Reinhart, C M, K S Rogoff and M A Savastano (2014) “Addicted to dollars”, Annals of Economics and Finance, 15(1): 1-52.

Reinhart, C M and C Trebesch (2014) “A distant mirror of debt, default, and relief”, NBER Working Paper, No. w20577.

Rose, A (2007) “Checking out: Exits from currency unions”, CEPR Discussion Paper 6254; see also Vox EU February 6, 2008.

Savastano, M A (1996) “Dollarization in Latin America: Recent evidence and some policy issues”, in P Mizen and E Pentecost (eds), The macroeconomics of international currencies: Theory, policy, and evidence, Edward Elgar, Brookfield, VT.

Footnotes

1 Rose (2007) tracked exits from currency unions over the post-WWII period, which averaged about one per year in his sample and are often associated with newly won independence.

2 In Israel, in late 1985, the authorities introduced a one-year mandatory holding period for all deposits in foreign currency, making those deposits substantially less attractive than other indexed financial instruments (see Bufman and Leiderman 1992).

3 In 1999 (during a year-long external debt restructuring), Pakistan froze foreign currency deposits – but this was less draconian than the conversions listed here and, thus not included (see Reinhart et al. 2014 for details).

4 Capital flight is estimated as the sum of net private capital inflows plus net errors and omissions in the balance of payments accounts. These are, on the whole lower-bound estimates, as they do not factor in mis-invoicing of trade. Estimates of export under-invoicing and import over-invoicing add significantly to the figures reported here during these periods.

5 As we do not observe the counterfactual, this is a tentative interpretation.

6 In 1977, Mexico began to allow its banks to receive foreign currency deposits, notably US dollars. These deposits were called Mex-dollars. By August 16, 1982, falling oil prices, rising US interest rates, and weak fiscal fundamentals drove the country to default on its external debts. On September 1, capital controls were imposed, banks were nationalized, and foreign currency deposits were prohibited and forcibly converted to pesos. As it was wryly observed at the time, Mex-dollars became ex-dollars.

This article is published in collaboration with VoxEU. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Carmen M. Reinhart is the Minos A. Zombanakis Professor of the International Financial System at Harvard Kennedy School.

Image: A European Union flag (L) flutters next to a Greek flag on the facade of the Bank of Greece headquarters in Athens April 14, 2015. REUTERS/Alkis Konstantinidis.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

European Union

Related topics:
Economic GrowthGeographies in Depth
Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how European Union is affecting economies, industries and global issues
A hand holding a looking glass by a lake
Crowdsource Innovation
Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale
World Economic Forum logo
Global Agenda

The Agenda Weekly

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

Subscribe today

You can unsubscribe at any time using the link in our emails. For more details, review our privacy policy.

How 'green education' could speed up the net-zero transition

Sonia Ben Jaafar

November 22, 2024

What is the gig economy and what's the deal for gig workers?

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum