Economic Growth

How can cities improve their productivity?

Alex Klein

Benefits of agglomeration

There is increasing recognition in European countries that successful cities are important in raising productivity and competing successfully in a globalised world. In this context, a major report recently explored the portfolio of cities that the Netherlands should seek to develop over the next few decades in terms of the optimal degree of diversification or specialisation of economic activity (CPB 2010). Similarly, in the UK, there is intense interest in the possibility of creating a ‘northern powerhouse’ to exploit productivity benefits from agglomeration.

This newfound emphasis on cities is underpinned by academic research in the new economic geography tradition which has provided increasingly solid evidence that cities offer externalities that raise labour productivity (Combes and Gobillon 2014).  The sources of agglomeration externalities can be categorised as sharing, matching, and learning mechanisms. Sharing mechanisms include sharing indivisible facilities, the gains from a wider variety of input suppliers and from a finer division of labour, or sharing risks. Matching mechanisms include better expected quality and/or higher probability of matches especially between employers and workers in a larger labour market. Learning mechanisms relate to the diffusion and accumulation of knowledge including tacit knowledge which is enhanced by the proximity of other producers.  Benefits of agglomeration that occur within industries are fostered by specialisation within cities while those which are inter-sectoral accrue from industrial diversity. Conventionally, the former are described as Marshallian (Marshall 1890) and the latter are termed Jacobian (Jacobs 1969). An important issue for policymakers is whether specialisation or diversity is more conducive to agglomeration externalities.  The evidence for the present day gives support to the existence of both Marshallian and Jacobian externalities but suggests that the former predominate (Harris and Moffat 2012). In turn, the ability to exploit these gains from specialisation depends on transport systems that facilitate trade between cities at home or abroad.

Agglomeration externalities in US cities, early 20th century

Our recent research (Klein and Crafts 2015) explores agglomeration externalities in manufacturing in cities in the US around the turn of the 20th century, about which there has been little quantitative evidence hitherto. This is an important period when the US took over industrial leadership from the UK during the so-called ‘2nd Industrial Revolution’. It was also the point at which the development of low-cost transport of freight led to a much better integration of the internal market and inaugurated the era of mass distribution and mass production (Chandler 1977).

We examine the relationship between labour productivity growth in US cities at the sector level and the industrial structure of the city.

  • We show that there is a strong causal effect of greater industrial specialisation on productivity growth, but that increased diversity reduced productivity growth except in very large cities.

This is consistent with the increasing body of evidence in the new economic geography literature that Marshallian externalities are important. During the decades at the end of the 19th and beginning of the 20th centuries, specialisation in US cities increased considerably, underpinned by improved inter-city transport (Pred 1966).

Our measure of specialisation shows an average increase of 24.9% across our sample of cities (see Table 1). For example, between 1890 and 1920, the specialisation index of Chicago increased by 10%, that of Baltimore by 25%, and that of Akron, Ohio by 36%. Using our preferred regression, this implies that labour productivity in manufacturing in our sample of cities was just over 23% higher in 1920 than if specialisation had remained at the 1890 level. Table 2 develops some further aspects of this result while taking account of workers in manufacturing outside these cities whose productivity is assumed to be unaffected.

  • The bottom line is that, in the absence of this increase in specialisation within cities, labour productivity growth in US manufacturing between 1890 and 1920 would have been almost 0.5 percentage points per year lower.

Table 1.  Specialisation in US cities, 1890-1920

1890 1920 Philadelphia 0.011 0.012 Chicago 0.012 0.013 Chicago 0.015 0.020 Cleveland 0.017 0.019 New Orleans 0.019 0.038 Albany, NY 0.025 0.048 Columbus, OH 0.028 0.045 Memphis 0.038 0.048 Savannah 0.043 0.067 Akron, OH 0.045 0.071

Note: The specialisation index of a city is defined as the average of city-industry specialisation indices across all industrial in a city. The city-industry specialisation index is calculated as aratio of city-industry employment to total city employment
Source: US Census of Manufactures 1890, 1920.

Table 2.  Counterfactual US manufacturing labour productivity in 1920

Actual 1890 specialisation Output in cities ($bn.) 16.272 13.213 Output/worker in cities ($) 3000.2 2436.2 Total output ($ bn.) 23.842 20.783 Total output/worker 2816.5 2455.2 Labour productivity growth, 1890-1920 (% p.a.) 0.85 0.36

Source: Klein and Crafts (2015, Table 12)

If this specialisation gain was largely due to the decline in freight rates on railroads, as the literature suggests but has not yet shown, then this has important implications for one of the most famous episodes in cliometrics, namely, the debate on the social savings of US railroads that was triggered by Fogel (1964). Gains from increased specialisation in American cities would be an important externality in the transport-using sector – in the jargon of modern cost-benefit analysis, a ‘wider economic benefit’ – which is not captured by Fogel’s measurement technique.

What can policymakers today, interested in the ‘successful cities’ agenda, learn from this research? We think there are three important lessons:

  • The evolution of cities does matter for the productivity agenda.
  • Generally speaking, the most important productivity advantages of cities accrue from specialisation.
  • Significant wider economic benefits from investment in transport infrastructure can result from induced changes in the structure of economic activity in urban areas.

It is important that these points are taken on board in cost-benefit analyses of putative investments in transport infrastructure, but they do need to be carefully quantified rather than simply asserted.

References

Chandler, A D (1977), The Visible Hand, Cambridge, Mass: Belknap Press.

Combes, P-P and L Gobillon (2014), “The Empirics of Agglomeration Economies”, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 10174.

CPB (2010), The Netherlands of 2040, The Hague.

Fogel, R W (1964), Railroads and American Economic Growth, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.

Harris, R and J Moffat (2012), “Is Productivity Higher in British Cities?”, Journal of Regional Science, 52, 762-786.

Jacobs, J (1969), The Economy of Cities,  New York: Random House.

Klein, A and N Crafts (2015), “Agglomeration Economies and Productivity Growth: U.S. Cities, 1880-1930”, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 10673.

Marshall, A (1890), Principles of Economics, London: Macmillan.

Pred, A R (1966), The Spatial Dynamics of U. S. Urban-Industrial Growth, 1800-1914,  Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

This article is published in collaboration with VoxEU. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.

To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.

Author: Alex Klein is a Senior Lecturer in Economics at the University of Kentr. Nicholas Crafts is Professor of Economics and Economic History at the University of Warwick.

Image: A ship travels north on the Hudson river past the Manhattan borough of New York City. REUTERS/Mike Segar.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

Infrastructure

Related topics:
Economic GrowthFinancial and Monetary Systems
Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Infrastructure is affecting economies, industries and global issues
World Economic Forum logo

Forum Stories newsletter

Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.

Subscribe today

How can we transform the economic growth we have into the growth we want?

Council on the Future of Growth and 2023-2024

December 20, 2024

AI-driven growth: Navigating the path to new markets

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum