Does market volatility increase the risk of financial crises?
Received wisdom maintains that financial market volatility has a direct impact on the likelihood of a financial crisis.
Perhaps the best expression of this is Minsky’s (1982) hypothesis that economic agents observing low financial risk are induced to increase risk-taking, which in turn may lead to a crisis. This is the foundation of his famous statement that “stability is destabilising”.
More recently, this sentiment has been echoed by policymakers:
“Volatility in markets is at low levels, both actual and expected… to the extent that low levels of volatility may induce risk-taking behavior is a concern to me and to the Committee”
Federal Reserve Chair Janet Yellen, 18 June 2014
Such views find support in the recent theoretical literature describing how economic agents react to volatility deviating from the level they come to expect it to be at.
Low volatility induces economic agents to take more risk, endogenously increasing the likelihood of future shocks. If the economic conditions deteriorate and the resulting bad investment decisions start to sour, volatility then increases, signalling a pending crisis.
However, we could not find any empirical literature documenting such a relationship between financial market volatility, risk-taking, the real economy, and crises. Perhaps we have made little empirical progress since Paul Samuelson’s famous quip in 1966 that “Wall Street indexes predicted nine out of the last five recessions”!
The decomposition of volatility
This lack of empirical clarity motivates us to take a new approach to verifying the volatility-crisis relationship, focusing on unexpectedly high and unexpectedly low volatility.
Crises are rare events – recent history notwithstanding, an OECD member country suffers a banking crisis only once every 35 years, on average. Consequently, in order to obtain a meaningful statistical relationship between volatility and crises, it is helpful to take a long-term historical view.
Since no comprehensive data on historical volatilities are available, we constructed such a database, spanning 1800 to 2010 and covering 60 countries, from primary sources.
We make use of Reinhart and Rogoff’s (2009) banking and stock market dataset as our crisis indicator and use GDP per capita, inflation, change in the government debt-to-GDP ratio, institution quality and fixed effects as controls.
We then run a binomial regression model on the incidence of financial crises with lagged averages of volatility and controls as explanatory variables, finding little significance.
We surmise that this is due in part to the theoretical literature emphasising volatility expectations and deviations therefrom, not the contemporaneous level of volatility.
Furthermore, the volatility trend evolves slowly over time, and one can identify regimes of high or low volatility that last for many years and even decades. Consequently, the expected level of volatility can be quite different across countries and across time, weakening any empirical analysis focused solely on volatility levels.
We address this by decomposing volatility into unexpectedly low and high volatility and using this as an explanatory variable in the regression model.
In particular, borrowing terminology from the literature on output gaps, we interpret the slow-running volatility trend, calculated by a one-sided Hodrick-Prescott filter, as long-term expected volatility. Unexpectedly high and low volatility is then the deviation of volatility above and below its trend, respectively.
Validating Minsky
We find a strong and significant relationship between unexpected volatility and the likelihood of a financial crisis.
Unexpectedly low volatility increases the probability of both a banking and a stock market crisis. This is especially strong if low volatility persists for half a decade or longer.
We further investigate this by using the credit-to-GDP gap as a proxy for risk-taking, finding that unexpectedly low volatility significantly increases risk-taking. This result complements that of Taylor and Schularick (2009), who find that credit booms are destabilising, leading to a banking crisis.
High volatility also increases the likelihood of a stock market crisis – but not a banking crisis – though with much shorter lags of up to two or three years.
This is very much in line with what theory predicts and provides strong evidence for Minsky’s instability hypothesis. Low volatility induces risk-taking, which leads to riskier investments. When those turn sour, the resulting high volatility signals a pending crisis.
These results are robust to a number of alternative specifications, for example, on the definition of volatility, filtering, lag lengths, sample selections and model specifications.
We find that the relationship between unexpected volatility and the likelihood of a future crisis becomes stronger over time. This is not surprising, since the importance of stock markets and the prevalence of limited liability corporations have steadily been increasing.
The main exception to this is the Bretton Woods era, when financial markets were tightly regulated and capital flows controlled, causing the volatility-crisis relationship to weaken significantly.
Conclusion
While the common view is that volatility directly affects the probability of a crisis, this has proven difficult to verify empirically.
In what we believe is the first study to do so, we find direct empirical evidence that the level of volatility is not a good indicator of crisis, but that unexpectedly high or low volatility is.
This is directly in line with what is predicted by theory and provides a validation of Minsky’s hypothesis that “stability is destabilising”.
Market volatility is of clear interest to policymakers, with the quote of chairwoman Yellen above being just one example.
By documenting how volatility can affect the risk-taking behaviour of economic agents, and hence the incidence of financial crises, policymakers and market participants alike would gain a valuable tool for understanding crises, tail events and systemic risk.
Bibliography
Danielsson, J, M Valenzuela, and I Zer (2015), “Learning from History: Volatility and Financial Crises”, SSRN.
Minsky, H (1992), “The financial instability hypothesis”, Working Paper.
Reinhart, C M and K S Rogoff (2009), “This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly”, Princeton University Press.
Samuelson, P (1966), “Science and stocks”, Newsweek.
Taylor, S (2009), “Credit booms go wrong”, VoxEU, 8 December, available at http://www.voxeu.org/article/credit-booms-go-wrong.
Yellen, J (2014), press conference, Federal Reserve Board, 18 June.
This article is published in collaboration with VoxEU. Publication does not imply endorsement of views by the World Economic Forum.
To keep up with the Agenda subscribe to our weekly newsletter.
Author: Jon Danielsson is the director of the ESRC funded Systemic Risk Centre at the London School of Economics. Marcela Valenzuela is an assistant professor at the University of Chile. Ilknur Zer is an economist at the Federal Reserve Board.
Image: A view shows the headquarters of a French business in Courbevoie, outside Paris. REUTERS.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Financial and Monetary Systems
Related topics:
Forum Stories newsletter
Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.
More on Economic GrowthSee all
Council on the Future of Growth and 2023-2024
December 20, 2024