Trade and Investment

The world is turning its back on the inventor. This is what needs to change

Economic growth is driven by growth in productivity, which is driven by the creation of new technologies.

Edmund S. Phelps
Director, The Center on Capitalism and Society, Columbia University
Eskil Ullberg
Adjunct Professor of Economics, George Mason University

If developed and developing countries’ national patent systems were integrated in the trade system, the result would be greater specialization among inventors and, with it, faster technological invention and productivity growth. Yet under current arrangements, World Trade Organization member states do not honor foreign inventors’ claims to their own inventions. More than ever, the world needs a new framework of trade rules to facilitate the exchange of human ideas across borders.

Image: IMF

Economic growth is essentially driven by growth in productivity, which, in turn, is driven by the creation of new technologies. In today’s world, such innovations are increasingly being developed as a result of coordination among inventors across companies and countries. Yet productivity growth has been sluggish for more than 50 years, owing significantly to gaps in trade rules, intellectual-property mercantilism through “forced technology transfer,” and the weakening of national patent systems. These factors have shut out grassroots inventors. The current environment admits only powerful players, effectively excluding millions of ideas from global markets.

Clearly, a more cooperative strategy is needed 1. We believe that a framework of cross-border technological exchange based on patent system protection and enforcement mechanisms can release the creativity of developed and developing economies alike 2. With the right rules, a non-discriminatory, open market for patented technology – as in the 1883 Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property – would create incentives for more crossborder collaboration.

. We believe that a framework of cross-border technological exchange based on patent system protection and enforcement mechanisms can release the creativity of developed and developing economies alike. With the right rules, a non-discriminatory, open market for patented technology – as in the 1883 Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property – would create incentives for more crossborder collaboration.

Of course, making such an initiative work poses major challenges. We need a global framework that puts into practice the principle of mutual gains through inventions, and which includes all people, regardless of their country of origin. That means further integrating existing patent systems into the trade system – honoring the inventor – and adopting common rules that are incentive-compatible with the emerging digital economy.

The focus should be on achieving productivity gains through markets in patent licenses and transfers, by experimenting with different rules and implementing those that produce desirable outcomes. Such an institutional learning process would likely transform the trade system and bring about more cross-border cooperation.

At present, however, WTO rules are holding back growth, because they fail to encourage firms to “share” their technology with one another by trading or licensing it. If a firm pursuing specific inventions can license parts of another firm’s patent portfolio, even on the margins, then it can focus more on the specialized fields where it is best performing.

Thus, specialization would lead to more productive inventions. What is needed is WTO trade rules that create the conditions for such specialization by establishing a market for trade in ideas, particularly between developed and developing countries. With such a market in place, investment would be directed to fields where the productivity gains are the highest.

Under the framework we envision, practices such as forced technology transfers would be curtailed. Conditioning market access on technology transfer does allow developing countries to “catch up” to developed countries, but it also weakens the prospects for long-term productivity growth. By eliminating incentives for inventors to benefit from the trade in patents, forced technology transfers effectively destroy the market in ideas.

Moreover, countries that engage in this practice weaken their own economic potential, by driving their inventors to countries that will protect their rights. The practice is similar to Tudor England’s grants of royal monopolies, which were used to replenish the king’s coffers. This mercantilist policy was abolished by the 1623 Statute of Monopolies, which granted property rights to the “true and first inventor,” thus establishing England’s patent system.

And yet, since the 1952-1954 period, advanced economies have adhered to the patentability criteria of “non-obviousness” (in the United States) and “inventive steps” (in Europe). These concepts effectively replaced the “flashof-genius” doctrine with one of “long toil,” with the result that rewards now accrue more easily to “marginal” inventions than to “broad” ones. There is less of an incentive to make high-risk investments in new productivity-enhancing technologies, because one can simply add “features” to existing products. The 500-year-old principle of honoring the inventor – first established in Venice in 1474– has been cast aside.

But creating an international market in patents would likely boost the growth of productivity-enhancing technologies only if effective rules-based incentives are in place. That requires three steps. First, the WTO would need to 5 begin the diplomatic process of transforming itself into a body that enforces market principles for patents (and other IP). As a result, the WTO’s membership could narrow, because a provision for excluding member states may be necessary to enforce compliance in this area.

Next, to start the process of institutional learning, the WTO would encourage member states to test out new rules governing the trade in patents. Once decided, these rules would be incorporated into existing treaties. Finally, the WTO would enforce those rules among the participating countries, and among any countries wishing to enter or re-enter the bloc.

Incorporating the national patent systems into the global trade framework would create strong incentives for cooperation, sharing, and exchange between inventors from developed and developing countries. At the same time, strategies based on abusing IP would increasingly fall out of favor, owing to the threat of “expulsion” from the new WTO and especially loss of trade gains.

Have you read?

The new system would empower creative people everywhere – including in least-developed countries. The kind of mass flourishing that we need depends on grassroots innovation, and on a non-materialist “culture of creativity” that maximizes human potential, rather than only seeking to satisfy basic needs 4.

There is no time to waste. We should start exploring options to integrate patent markets in the trade system. The United States, the European Union, Japan, South Korea, China and many developing countries all have important roles to play. Those countries that are not on board risk falling behind, just as much of the world did in the 1600s, when Western countries expanded their patent systems and raced ahead.

Let the transformation begin!

References:

1 See Ullberg, “The Language of Trust and Reciprocity in Patent Markets: A Sociological Analysis of Property Rights on Messages Resolving Uncertainty in Exchange in Ideas,” IP2 Hoover Institute WP#15016 (December, 2015): https://hooverip2.org/working-paper/wp15016/

2 See Ullberg, “Trade in Ideas: Performance and Behavioral Properties of Markets in Patents” (New York: Springer-Verlag, 2012).

3 See “Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property,” WIPO Database of Intellectual Property Legislative Texts (March, 1883): https://www.unido.org/sites/default/files/2014- 04/Paris_Convention_0.pdf .

4 For further elaboration on these ideas, see Phelps, Mass Flourishing: How Grassroots Innovation Created Jobs, Challenge, and Change (Princeton, 2013).

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

Sign up for free

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Stay up to date:

Innovation

Share:
The Big Picture
Explore and monitor how Innovation is affecting economies, industries and global issues
World Economic Forum logo

Forum Stories newsletter

Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.

Subscribe today

2:06

Agility: Empowering SMEs to Navigate Global Trade

What's 'bi-globalization' and could this be the near future for geo-economics and global trade?

About us

Engage with us

  • Sign in
  • Partner with us
  • Become a member
  • Sign up for our press releases
  • Subscribe to our newsletters
  • Contact us

Quick links

Language editions

Privacy Policy & Terms of Service

Sitemap

© 2024 World Economic Forum