What is the link between financial risk and economic growth?
The link between perceptions of risk and economic growth. Image: Kleomenis Spyroglou/Unsplash
- New research explores the link between perceived financial risk and economic growth.
- It finds the global risk environment is more significant than the local.
- The research has particular implications for policy areas such as macroprudential regulations and monetary policy
The global crisis in 2008 reminded us of the importance of the financial sector for the macroeconomy, a lesson many had forgotten in the decades after the previous global crisis, the Great Depression. Financial risk matters. It is necessary for investment and growth, while also driving uncertainty, inefficiency, recessions, and crises.
Our interest here is in how financial risk affects economic growth, casting light on the power of monetary policy to stimulate growth, the ability of macroprudential policies to tame systemic risk, and the relative importance of the US in driving global risk perceptions.
The relationship between financial risk and growth might seem straightforward. High risk is certainly detrimental to growth (e.g. Ahir et al. 2019, Bloom 2009). That leaves the question of how low risk affects growth.
We ask that very question in Danielsson et al. (2021), where we propose a new theoretical and empirical framework for analysing how risk interacts with the macroeconomy. We surmise that the strength of agents’ beliefs in the accuracy of their risk estimates is of key importance, driving investment decisions and capital flows, and ultimately affecting future instability and growth.
How low risk affects growth
We find that the impact of low risk on the macroeconomy is very different from high risk. When economic agents perceive risk to be high, economic growth suffers, while perceptions of low risk have a boom-to-bust effect: initially positive but eventually turning negative.
The reason for the asymmetric impact of low versus high risk has its roots in the inability to directly measure risk and the evolution of financial leverage. Risk is a latent variable, we can’t directly measure it, having to use a model to infer risk from market prices.
What that means in practice is that when agents receive a low risk reading, it does not necessarily mean that risk is actually low, and the agents know that. They want to be convinced that risk is really low before they embark on costly investments.
Formally, the agents have a posterior belief in the accuracy of their risk measurements, and that posterior belief is key to understanding their investment behaviour. In our empirical investigation, we propose a proxy of the posterior belief – duration of low risk (DLR).
A firm belief in risk being low boosts optimism and increases agents’ appetite for risk, thus driving investment. Moreover, asset prices increase in such tranquil periods (Danielsson et al. 2009, Brunnermeier and Pedersen 2009). Hence, beliefs, financial frictions, and risk-taking incentives interact: willingness to take on more risk, increased asset prices, and easier credit conditions all drive growth – the boom in the boom-to-bust cycle.
Over time, as low risk persists, the supply of good investments falls and the riskiness of investments increases, rendering the financial system increasingly fragile. A chain of events consistent with Minsky’s dictum, “stability is destabilising”, laying the seed for a reversal – the bust in the boom-to-bust cycle.
Even then, the overall impact of perceptions of low risk on growth is positive, except when credit growth has been particularly high and/or the low-risk environment has persisted for a time. That is exactly the result we see during the global crisis in 2008: excessive credit growth coupled with robust risk appetite fuelled a boom-to-bust cycle that culminated in 2008.
The global environment is particularly important. Perceptions of low global risk, global DLR, have more than twice the impact of local risk on growth. Here the US is dominant, in line with extent results on the global nexus, accounting for about two-thirds of global risk perceptions.
The impact of global DLR on growth is achieved via three main channels – investments, capital flows, and the riskiness of bond issuance – all of which show the same boom-to-bust response to global low risk as growth, whereas local risk has only a negligible effect.
We show the mechanism for how low and high risk affects growth in Figure 1.
Figure 1 Perceived risk and growth
Our theoretical and empirical approach
Our starting point is a model of financial volatility, where a Markov-switching process governs high or low volatility states. While the risk state is latent, the agents can obtain a signal of it and, by using a Bayesian learning model, construct a posterior belief of risk really being low. It is that posterior belief which drives their appetite for risk.
While we don't observe the posterior, we can construct a sufficient proxy for it, DLR, which increases with the number of years a country stays in a low volatility environment, at a decreasing rate.
We construct DLR by estimating annual realised volatility, calculating its trend, and using the deviation from trend to identify the volatility state – high or low – which then feeds into the calculation of DLR.
In order to estimate the relationship between risk perceptions and growth, we assembled a large panel of 73 countries spanning 1900 to 2016, with an average of 55 years of observations per country. We then calculate the annual realised volatility using 12-monthly real stock returns for each country and use deviations from a one-sided trend filter to construct the DLR. After obtaining the DLR estimates, we calculate the global DLR as the GDP weighted average across all countries with data in a particular year.
We show the global DLR in Figure 2.
Figure 2 Global duration of low risk and major economic events
We examine the effects of DLR on growth contemporaneously and up to five years into the future, with impulse response functions obtained from Jordà's (2005) local projection method.
DLR has a positive impact on growth contemporaneously and especially the year after, followed by a reversal in year two. The impact of global DLR on growth is much stronger than local DLR.
Finally, global DLR has a similar boom-to-bust impact on capital flows, aggregate investment, and bond market debt-issuer quality.
The main findings are robust to a range of alternative specifications and parameterizations and when the endogeneity concerned are alleviated.
Wider implications
Taken together, our results have a direct impact on several important policy debates.
Start with the importance of global risk. National policymakers concerned with growth are constrained by global financial cycles, captured by global DLR. Thus, there are limits to monetary policy independence. Even if a domestic monetary authority intends to stimulate or cool down the economy, global risk perceptions and how they drive risk-taking may override domestic monetary policy decisions.
Furthermore, since the crisis of 2008, policymakers, justifiably intent on preventing a repeat, have been actively aiming to reduce the amount of risk financial institutions can take, thus de-risking the financial system. While such de-risking promises to reduce the likelihood of costly crises, it also affects growth, pointing to the importance of policymakers considering the joint impact of macroprudential policies and risk perceptions on the likelihood of crises and growth.
There is a further lesson for financial authorities, as our results suggest that agents base their investment decisions on their risk perceptions, which are formed by past market outcomes. As the policy authorities cannot change such risk perceptions, they may find their attempts to stimulate or cool the economy down futile if the agents’ risk perceptions point them towards different investment decisions than those desired by the authorities.
Conclusion
We investigate the relationship between financial risk and economic growth, with a focus on global risk.
We find that the global risk environment is twice as important as the local risk environment.
While perceptions of high global risk unambiguously reduce growth, the impact of low risk is more subtle, starting out as positive but then turning negative. Even then, the overall impact is positive.
The two exceptions are very long-lasting periods of low risk and excessive credit growth, providing support for financial vulnerability driven economic contractions.
How is the Forum helping to navigate global value chain disruption?
Furthermore, even though US risk has a powerful impact on global growth, the aggregate global volatility environment exerts a much stronger impact than the US by itself.
Taken together, our results shed new light on how financial markets and the macroeconomy are related, with particular implications for policy areas such as macroprudential regulations and monetary policy.
Don't miss any update on this topic
Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.
License and Republishing
World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.
The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.
Stay up to date:
Financial and Monetary Systems
Related topics:
Forum Stories newsletter
Bringing you weekly curated insights and analysis on the global issues that matter.
More on Financial and Monetary SystemsSee all
Rishi Kapoor
December 20, 2024